The task of scientific socialism in the 21th century should be to understand the laws of motion that govern capitalism in order to ultimately, replace them with the “laws of socialist planning”. Both parts, the descriptive analysis of “the law of value” and the development of a political program in accordance to a future “law of socialist planning” are crucial for the existence of a lively and healthy research program for scientific socialism.
However, I would argue that the current research program of scientific socialism is degenerate, and almost dead, even if there is a an existing community of thinkers and writers that develop radical theory. Since the critical theory turn of the Left after the 1960s, partly due to the absorption of marxism into the humanities, the “scientific” impetus of what was once known as “scientific socialism” has been more or less lost. The main reasons for the degeneration of the socialist science are: (i) extreme, self-referential formalism, (ii) a turn towards the critical and descriptive, but without prescription, and {iii} disdain for the empirical and quantitative. The original purpose of this blog, was in fact, to combat these three anti-scientific tendencies, by offering prescriptive, transparent, and eclectic content that could generate discussion. I will describe these three issues in the following paragraphs.
Issue (i) is the one that definitely bothers me the most – namely that much of radical theory has devolved into an a closed, exercise of exegesis – from graduate students finding the meaning of the universe in Marx’s Capital or the Grundrisse, sectarian cadre getting their political education from primary source pamphlets (e.g. Lenin, Marx, Mao), to cultural capital waxing in the form of opaque prose that cites dead frenchmen. This exercise takes the form of a closed self-referential loop that employs a horde of writers, thinkers and sect gurus but does not say much about the world. Contemporary marxism is completely diseased with this problem, where a social or economic phenomenon suddenly becomes a platform for the exegesis of Marx’ s Capital (or in its sectarian form, a pamphlet of Lenin or Mao), with academics, bloggers, and autodidacts finding every excuse to cite a chapter of Capital in every paragraph of an essay/book. It is a form of primary-source dogmatism that forms a closed, self-referential system of signals and glyphs that refuses to open up to the outside. Instead of, for example, engaging academic, secondary sources in sociology, history, finance, “bourgeois” economics, and business, in order to synthesize information using Marx as a rough, heuristical guide, all empirical reality is simply filtered through the passages of Capital. This primary-source dogmatism reveals itself in the numerous reading circles that exist around Capital, rather than that time being spent more fruitfully reading a secondary source on Capital (in the same way physicists learn Newton’s Laws through a textbook not through the Principia) and instead engaging with current scientific literature to form a synthesis. Indeed, if anything, this is entirely the opposite of what Marx did! Marx studied the cutting edge of his era in mathematics, “bourgeois” economics, and history, to form a synthesis; he didn’t bind every paragraph he wrote to a reference from Hegel’s Phenomenology!
One probable sociological cause behind issue (i) is the phenomenon of gate-keeping. Privileging the mastery of obtuse and unreadable subject matter and also a specific form of method creates a pecking order of gurus and academics who use this “mastery” to justify their social or economic position, not unlike the function of medieval guilds. Yet this extreme formalism is often confounded with the traditional form of specialization – where a doctor an engineer require authentic mastery of technically challenging skills to be adept at their work. Instead, the formalism acquired in academia or through politico-sectarian education can often act as a straightjacket because it imposes limits into how much can be imported from other disciplines, or how much can the method change; in their eyes, going beyond method and discipline turns you into a “crank”, “dilettante” or “eclectic”. However, as Feyerabrand once pointed out, young scientific research programs require precisely of “cranks”, epistemological anarchists that throwing shit against the wall and see what sticks, in order to flourish.
Issue (ii), the lack of positive, political programs as opposed to the overproduction of descriptive criticism, is deeply connected to issue (i) given that it is related to the academic-formalist straightjacket for two reasons: (a) reluctance to engage in interdisciplinary research with other academic sciences inhibits to ability to formulate solutions because of lack of knowledge of the concrete (logistical, managerial, financial, scientific) issues of capitalism, and (b) it is much more academically respectable to engage in descriptive criticism as opposed to formulate radical, concrete solutions. In the case of (a), the hard physics of capitalism are disregarded (which require knowledge on finance, economics, computer science and logistics which can only be acquired through inter-disciplinary and crank-eclectic study) and instead the discourse is saturated with “soft” concepts such as alienation, power, and knowledge, and “value” (some of these concepts related to the formalism of literary and critical studies), so that the discourse is too abstracted to formulate a concrete, political solution to a given problem. In the case of (b), it’s just simply more congruent with academic formalism to dissect critically the problems of capitalism (and civilization) without suggesting a political solution that amounts to more than just soft, fuzzy platitudes. The problem is that, although it is understanding why academia does not have space for radical, political prescriptions, this “critical-descriptivism” is exported outside academia, to the more general radical millieu. Although a partial, neutered shell of the the old “scientific marxism” still endures in some history or sociology departments, the fact is that these tools are merely used to academically dissect social phenomena without asserting a positive prescription for a better world.
Finally, issue (iii), the general disdain for the quantitative and the empirical, is simply a result of innumeracy and scientific ignorance that comes from the “academic-formalist” straight jacket described in the preceding sections. Although it is understanding that a person cannot master all subjects, the language and culture of the Left is very alienating to trained scientists and engineers that could collaborate, and the opacity of radical theory due to self-referential formalism gathered from pamphlets or “dead frenchmen” makes it hard for trained scientists to access. Finally, since the 60s, the Left has developed a counter-enlightment and “social constructivist” critique of the quantitative positivism of the hard sciences, which often makes the milieu uninviting to engineering/science types.
It used to be that the workers’ movement was a haven for unorthodox, eclectic-crank types that definitely made the socialist research program alive and useful. Some names that come to mind are: Bogdanov, Dietzgen, and Preobrazhensky. Many of these thinkers were often wrong, and often their ideas amounted to little more than crackpot fodder. Yet, the fact that they were not shy to throw shit against the wall and see what sticks gave rise to politically (and also academically) useful narratives on imperialism, revolution, and socialist planning. This old, eclectic crank spirit has been replaced by ossified pamphlets and sterile academese. For the sake of scientific socialism in the 21th century, we must reinvigorate the eclectic-crank once again, as opposed to the measured and methodical “academic” thinker, or the dogmatic guru of the fossilized sects.