Protectionism

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Jump to: navigation, search
"Protectionist" redirects here. For other uses, see Protectionist (disambiguation).

In economics, protectionism is the economic policy of restraining trade between states (countries) through methods such as tariffs on imported goods, restrictive quotas, and a variety of other government regulations. Protectionist policies protect the producers, businesses and workers of the import-competing sector in a country from foreign competitors.[1] According to proponents, these policies can counteract unfair trade practices, to allow fair competition between imports and goods and services produced domestically. Protectionists may favor the policy in order to decrease the trade deficit, maintain employment in certain sectors, or favor the growth of certain industries.[2] In recent years, protectionism has become closely aligned with the anti-globalization movement.[3]

The doctrine of protectionism contrasts with the doctrine of free trade, where governments reduce as much as possible the barriers to trade. There is a broad consensus among economists that the impact of protectionism on economic growth (and on economic welfare in general) is largely negative, although the impact on specific industries and groups of people may be positive.[4]

Protectionist policies[edit]

A variety of policies have been used to achieve protectionist goals. These include:

  • Prevent foreign investors from taking control of domestic firms
  • Tariffs: Typically, tariffs (or taxes) are imposed on imported goods. Tariff rates usually vary according to the type of goods imported. Import tariffs will increase the cost to importers, and increase the price of imported goods in the local markets, thus lowering the quantity of goods imported, to favour local producers. Tariffs may also be imposed on exports, and in an economy with floating exchange rates, export tariffs have similar effects as import tariffs. However, since export tariffs are often perceived as 'hurting' local industries, while import tariffs are perceived as 'helping' local industries, export tariffs are seldom implemented.
  • Import quotas: To reduce the quantity and therefore increase the market price of imported goods. The economic effects of an import quota is similar to that of a tariff, except that the tax revenue gain from a tariff will instead be distributed to those who receive import licenses. Economists often suggest that import licenses be auctioned to the highest bidder, or that import quotas be replaced by an equivalent tariff.
  • Administrative barriers: Countries are sometimes accused of using their various administrative rules (e.g. regarding food safety, environmental standards, electrical safety, etc.) as a way to introduce barriers to imports.
  • Anti-dumping legislation: Supporters of anti-dumping laws argue that they prevent "dumping" of cheaper foreign goods that would cause local firms to close down. However, in practice, anti-dumping laws are usually used to impose trade tariffs on foreign exporters.
  • Direct subsidies: Government subsidies (in the form of lump-sum payments or cheap loans) are sometimes given to local firms that cannot compete well against imports. These subsidies are purported to "protect" local jobs, and to help local firms adjust to the world markets.
  • Export subsidies: Export subsidies are often used by governments to increase exports. Export subsidies have the opposite effect of export tariffs because exporters get payment, which is a percentage or proportion of the value of exported. Export subsidies increase the amount of trade, and in a country with floating exchange rates, have effects similar to import subsidies.
  • Exchange rate control: A government may intervene in the foreign exchange market to lower the value of its currency by selling its currency in the foreign exchange market. Doing so will raise the cost of imports and lower the cost of exports, leading to an improvement in its trade balance. However, such a policy is only effective in the short run, as it will lead to higher inflation in the country in the long run, which will in turn raise the real cost of exports, and reduce the relative price of imports.
  • International patent systems: There is an argument for viewing national patent systems as a cloak for protectionist trade policies at a national level. Two strands of this argument exist: one when patents held by one country form part of a system of exploitable relative advantage in trade negotiations against another, and a second where adhering to a worldwide system of patents confers "good citizenship" status despite 'de facto protectionism'. Peter Drahos explains that "States realized that patent systems could be used to cloak protectionist strategies. There were also reputational advantages for states to be seen to be sticking to intellectual property systems. One could attend the various revisions of the Paris and Berne conventions, participate in the cosmopolitan moral dialogue about the need to protect the fruits of authorial labor and inventive genius...knowing all the while that one's domestic intellectual property system was a handy protectionist weapon."[5]
  • Political campaigns advocating domestic consumption (e.g. the "Buy American" campaign in the United States, which could be seen as an extra-legal promotion of protectionism.)
  • Preferential governmental spending, such as the Buy American Act, federal legislation which called upon the United States government to prefer U.S.-made products in its purchases.

In the modern trade arena many other initiatives besides tariffs have been called protectionist. For example, some commentators, such as Jagdish Bhagwati, see developed countries efforts in imposing their own labor or environmental standards as protectionism. Also, the imposition of restrictive certification procedures on imports are seen in this light.

Further, others point out that free trade agreements often have protectionist provisions such as intellectual property, copyright, and patent restrictions that benefit large corporations. These provisions restrict trade in music, movies, pharmaceuticals, software, and other manufactured items to high cost producers with quotas from low cost producers set to zero.[6][7]

History[edit]

Historically, protectionism was associated with economic theories such as mercantilism (which focused on maintaining full employment, domestic industry, and a positive trade balance), and import substitution.

In the 18th century, Adam Smith famously warned against the "interested sophistry" of industry, seeking to gain advantage at the cost of the consumers.[8] Friedrich List saw Adam Smith's views on free trade as disingenuous, believing that Smith advocated for freer trade so that British industry could lock out underdeveloped foreign competition.[9]

In the late 19th Century, Germany also used protectionist measures to grow its industry.[10] After World War II, Japan followed that model.[11] It has been argued that Deng Xiaoping's post-Mao policies were inspired by List,[12] and that policies in India after independence were, as well.[13][14] It has been noted by Mehdi Shafaeddin that no major country has ever successfully industrialized without some form of economic protection.[15] This observation is likewise claimed by Eric Reinert,[16] Ian Fletcher,[17] and Spencer P Morrison.[18]

Protectionism in America[edit]

According to Michael Lind, protectionism was America's de facto policy from the passage of the Tariff of 1816 to World War II, "switching to free trade only in 1945, when most of its industrial competitors had been wiped out" by the war.[19] However, it has been argued that one of the underlying motivations for the American Revolution itself was a desire to industrialize, and reverse the trade deficit with Britain, which had grown by a factor of ten in the space of a few decades, from £67,000 (1721–30) to £739,000 (1761–70).[20]

The first U.S. Secretary of the Treasury, Alexander Hamilton, advocated tariffs to help protect infant industries in his "Report on Manufactures." Heeding Hamilton's advice, George Washington signed the Tariff Act of 1789, making it the Republic's second ever piece of legislation. Increasing the domestic supply of manufactured goods, particularly war materials, was seen as an issue of national security. Washington and Hamilton believed that political independence was predicated upon economic independence.[21]

For the most part, the "Jeffersonians" strongly opposed it. However, after the War of 1812, Thomas Jefferson himself acknowledged that tariffs were necessary for preventing import dependency, which undermined the nation's security. He confessed in a letter to his friend, Benjamin Austin in 1816:

…experience has taught me that manufactures are now as necessary to our independence as to our comfort: and if those who quote me as of a different opinion will keep pace with me in purchasing nothing foreign where an equivalent of domestic fabric can be obtained, without regard to difference of price…[22]

In the 19th century, statesmen such as Senator Henry Clay continued Hamilton's themes within the Whig Party under the name "American System."

The fledgling Republican Party led by Abraham Lincoln, who called himself a "Henry Clay tariff Whig", strongly opposed free trade, and implemented a 44-percent tariff during the Civil War—in part to pay for railroad subsidies and for the war effort, and to protect favored industries.[23] This policy was continued by Presidents Ulysses S Grant and Theodore Roosevelt.[21] William McKinley (later to become President of the United States) stated the stance of the Republican Party (which won every election for President from 1868 until 1912, except the two non-consecutive terms of Grover Cleveland) as thus:

Under free trade the trader is the master and the producer the slave. Protection is but the law of nature, the law of self-preservation, of self-development, of securing the highest and best destiny of the race of man. [It is said] that protection is immoral…. Why, if protection builds up and elevates 63,000,000 [the U.S. population] of people, the influence of those 63,000,000 of people elevates the rest of the world. We cannot take a step in the pathway of progress without benefitting mankind everywhere. Well, they say, 'Buy where you can buy the cheapest'…. Of course, that applies to labor as to everything else. Let me give you a maxim that is a thousand times better than that, and it is the protection maxim: 'Buy where you can pay the easiest.' And that spot of earth is where labor wins its highest rewards.[24]

In Kicking Away the Ladder, developmental economist Ha-Joon Chang reviews the history of free trade policies and economic growth, and notes that many of the now-industrialized countries had significant trade barriers throughout their history. The United States and Britain, sometimes considered the homes of free trade policy, employed protectionism to varying degrees at all times. During the 1820s, during the height of the Industrial Revolution, Britain's exports on manufactured goods stood at over 50%. In fact, it has been argued that the Industrial Revolution was only made possible due to protectionist policies, coupled with pressure from chronic warfare, which created a large incentive for Britain to invest in labor-saving devices.[18] Britain's turn to free trade only began in the middle of the century. In 1846 the Corn Laws, which restricted import of grain, were repealed due to domestic pressures caused by the Irish Potato Famine. Britain reduced protection rapidly until its industry began to collapse during the late 19th century, in response to pressure from American and German competition.[25]

The United States maintained weighted average tariffs on manufactured products of approximately 40–50% up until the 1950s, although they dipped to lows of roughly 10% during the 1920s, which were augmented by the natural protectionism of high transportation costs in the 19th century.[26] The most consistent practitioners of free trade have been Switzerland, the Netherlands, and to a lesser degree Belgium.[27] Chang describes the export-oriented industrialization policies of the Four Asian Tigers as "far more sophisticated and fine-tuned than their historical equivalents".[28]

Arguments for protectionism[edit]

Protectionists believe that there is a legitimate need for government restrictions on free trade in order to protect their country’s economic, and therefore political independence. This was the contention of the American School of economics.

Presidents George Washington,[29] Abraham Lincoln,[30] William McKinley,[31] and Theodore Roosevelt[32] were all strong advocates for protectionist policies, and could be considered proponents of the American School.

Protection leads to long-term growth[edit]

Economic historian Paul Bairoch has noted that economic protection is positively correlated with economic and industrial growth during the 19th century. For example, GNP growth during Europe's "liberal period" in the middle of the century (where tariffs were at their lowest), averaged 1.7% per year, while industrial growth averaged 1.8% per year. However, during the protectionist era of the 1870s and 1890s, GNP growth averaged 2.6% per year, while industrial output grew at 3.8% per year, roughly twice as fast as it had during the liberal era of low tariffs and free trade.[33] More recently, it has been shown that tariffs imposed on manufactured goods increase economic growth in developing countries by a significant margin, and this growth impact remains even after the tariffs are repealed.[34]

It is also argued that protection, calibrated in advanced industries, or those subject to increasing returns, benefits long-term economic growth because it maximizes the likelihood of black swan events, which lead to explosive, non-linear economic growth through technological gains. This is because protectionist policies artificially expand domestic production, thereby increasing exposure to discoveries, particularly if the measures are aimed at advanced, knowledge-generating industries.[20]

Infant industry argument[edit]

Protectionists postulate that new industries may require protection from entrenched foreign competition in order to develop. This was Alexander Hamilton's argument in his "Report on Manufactures", and the primary reason why George Washington signed the Tariff Act of 1789. The idea was that for America to retain her political independence, she must become economically independent. Mehdi Shafaeddin has noted that no major nation has ever industrialized without protectionist policies.[15] New Trade theorists also challenge the assumption of diminishing returns to scale. They argue that using protectionist measures to build up a large industrial base in industries with increasing returns (ie. manufacturing) can set those sectors up for international dominance once they mature.

Economic independence is necessary for political independence[edit]

It has been argued by politicians as ideologically disparate as Washington, John A MacDonald and Otto von Bismarck, that political independence is predicated upon economic independence, for the simple fact that if a country depends upon another for critical imports, then it must necessarily consider its trading partners interests, even to its own detriment.[21] This is particularly true for commodities like food, oil, or military equipment. Even Milton Friedman stated in his free trade manifesto "Free to Choose", admitted that import dependency poses a credible threat a country's security and sovereignty. His proposed solution was to maintain adequate stockpiles.[35] However, it is argued that doing so would undermine the benefits of free trade, and would be insufficient for a large-scale conflict. Instead, it may be more efficient to simply maintain a minimal level of industry using protective measures, that could be scaled up in times of need.[20]

Arguments against comparative advantage[edit]

Opponents of free trade have argued that comparative advantage does not apply in a globally integrated world, in which capital is free to move internationally.

David Ricardo himself was the first to recognize this critique, and duly noted that his theory only applied in situations where capital is immobile. Regarding his famous example, he wrote:

it would undoubtedly be advantageous to the capitalists [and consumers] of England… [that] the wine and cloth should both be made in Portugal [and that] the capital and labour of England employed in making cloth should be removed to Portugal for that purpose.[36]

Ricardo recognized that applying his theory in situations where capital was mobile would result in offshoring, and therefore economic decline and job loss. To correct for this, he argued that (i) most men of property [will be] satisfied with a low rate of profits in their own country, rather than seek[ing] a more advantageous employment for their wealth in foreign nations, and (ii) that capital was functionally immobile.[36] However, because capital is now mobile, it is argued that comparative advantage is not necessarily applicable in today's economy.

For evidence, protectionists point to the shifting of production to Mexico by US companies after the passing of the North American Free Trade Agreement as support for this argument. Herman Daly argues that: "Free capital mobility totally undercuts Ricardo's comparative advantage argument for free trade in goods, because that argument is explicitly and essentially premised on capital (and other factors) being immobile between nations. In the new global economy, capital tends simply to flow to wherever costs are lowest—that is, to pursue absolute advantage."[37]

Arguments against protectionism[edit]

Protectionism is frequently criticized by economists as harming the people it is meant to help. Mainstream economists instead support free trade.[8][38] The principle of comparative advantage shows that the gains from free trade outweigh any losses as free trade creates more jobs than it destroys because it allows countries to specialize in the production of goods and services in which they have a comparative advantage.[39] Protectionism results in deadweight loss; this loss to overall welfare gives no-one any benefit, unlike in a free market, where there is no such total loss. According to economist Stephen P. Magee, the benefits of free trade outweigh the losses by as much as 100 to 1.[40]

Economists, including Nobel prize winners Milton Friedman and Paul Krugman [4] believe that free trade helps workers in developing countries, even though they are not subject to the stringent health and labour standards of developed countries. This is because "the growth of manufacturing—and of the myriad other jobs that the new export sector creates—has a ripple effect throughout the economy" that creates competition among producers, lifting wages and living conditions.[41] Economists[who?] have suggested that those who support protectionism ostensibly to further the interests of workers in least developed countries are in fact being disingenuous, seeking only to protect jobs in developed countries.[42] Additionally, workers in the least developed countries only accept jobs if they are the best on offer, as all mutually consensual exchanges must be of benefit to both sides, or else they wouldn't be entered into freely. That they accept low-paying jobs from companies in developed countries shows that their other employment prospects are worse. A letter reprinted in the May 2010 edition of Econ Journal Watch identifies a similar sentiment against protectionism from 16 British economists at the beginning of the 20th century.[43]

Alan Greenspan, former chair of the American Federal Reserve, has criticized protectionist proposals as leading "to an atrophy of our competitive ability. ... If the protectionist route is followed, newer, more efficient industries will have less scope to expand, and overall output and economic welfare will suffer."[44]

Protectionism has also been accused of being one of the major causes of war. Proponents of this theory point to the constant warfare in the 17th and 18th centuries among European countries whose governments were predominantly mercantilist and protectionist, the American Revolution, which came about ostensibly due to British tariffs and taxes, as well as the protective policies preceding both World War I and World War II. According to a slogan of Frédéric Bastiat (1801–1850), "When goods cannot cross borders, armies will."[45]

Current world trends[edit]

Protectionist measures taken since 2008 according to Global Trade Alert.[46]

Since the end of World War II, it has been the stated policy of most First World countries to eliminate protectionism through free trade policies enforced by international treaties and organizations such as the World Trade Organization[47] Certain policies of First World governments have been criticized as protectionist, however, such as the Common Agricultural Policy[48] in the European Union, longstanding agricultural subsidies and proposed "Buy American" provisions[49] in economic recovery packages in the United States.

Heads of the G20 meeting in London on 2 April 2009 pledged "We will not repeat the historic mistakes of protectionism of previous eras". Adherence to this pledge is monitored by the Global Trade Alert,[50] providing up-to-date information and informed commentary to help ensure that the G20 pledge is met by maintaining confidence in the world trading system, detering beggar-thy-neighbor acts, and preserving the contribution that exports could play in the future recovery of the world economy.

Although they were reiterating what they had already committed to, last November in Washington, 17 of these 20 countries were reported by the World Bank as having imposed trade restrictive measures since then. In its report, the World Bank says most of the world's major economies are resorting to protectionist measures as the global economic slowdown begins to bite. Economists who have examined the impact of new trade-restrictive measures using detailed bilaterally monthly trade statistics estimated that new measures taken through late 2009 were distorting global merchandise trade by 0.25% to 0.5% (about $50 billion a year).[51]

Since then however, then-President-elect Donald Trump announced in November 2016 that he would abandon the TPP (Trans-Pacific Partnership) deal, placing the protectionist policies reflected in Trumponomics very much on the table, despite the wishes of all the other G20 nations.

See also[edit]

References[edit]

  1. ^ Xinhua (2012-05-24). "Trade-oriented Economy Boosts Growth, Employment". CRI English. Retrieved 26 May 2012. 
  2. ^ Xinhua (2012-05-24). "Trade-oriented Economy Boosts Growth, Employment". CRI English. Retrieved 26 May 2012. 
  3. ^ Jennifer Rubin. To understand how dumb our politics have become, listen to a real CEO. Washington Post Opinion blog post, 28 Sep 2016
  4. ^ a b See P.Krugman, «The Narrow and Broad Arguments for Free Trade», American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 83(3), 1993 ; and P.Krugman, Peddling Prosperity: Economic Sense and Nonsense in the Age of Diminished Expectations, New York, W.W. Norton & Company, 1994.
  5. ^ Peter Drahos; John Braithwaite (2002). Information Feudalism: Who Owns the Knowledge Economy?. London: Earthscan. p. 36. ISBN 9781853839177. 
  6. ^ [1] Archived October 17, 2006, at the Wayback Machine.
  7. ^ Baker, Dean. "Dean Baker: Economist - Author". 
  8. ^ a b Free to Choose, Milton Friedman
  9. ^ The National System of Political Economy, by Friedrich List, 1841, translated by Sampson S. Lloyd M.P., 1885 edition, Fourth Book, "The Politics", Chapter 33.
  10. ^ G. B. Curtiss, Protection and Prosperity; and W. H. Dawson, Protection in Germany (London, 1904)
  11. ^ List's influences Japan: see "(3) A contrary view: How the World Works, by James Fallows"
  12. ^ "berkeley.edu on List influences of Deng" (PDF). 
  13. ^ Frederick Clairmonte, "FRIEDRICH LIST AND THE HISTORICAL CONCEPT OF BALANCED GROWTH", Indian Economic Review, Vol. 4, No. 3 (February 1959), pp. 24–44.
  14. ^ Mauro Boianovsky, "Friedrich List and the economic fate of tropical countries", Universidade de Brasilia, June 2011, p. 2.
  15. ^ a b Shafaeddin, Mehdi (1998). "How did Developed Countries Industrialize? The History of Trade and Industrial Policy: the Cases of Great Britain and the USA". United Nations Conference on Trade and Development. 
  16. ^ Reinert, Eric (2007). How Rich Countries got Rich and Why Poor Countries Stay Poor. New York: Carroll & Graf. 
  17. ^ Fletcher, Ian (2010). Free Trade Doesn’t Work: What Should Replace it and Why. Washington DC: US Business & Industry Council. 
  18. ^ a b Morrison, Spencer P (2016). America Betrayed. Edmonton: Outremer Publishing. pp. 38, 52. 
  19. ^ Michael Lind, "Free Trade Fallacy", New America Foundation, January 1, 2003.
  20. ^ a b c Morrison, Spencer P (2016). America Betrayed. Edmonton: Outremer Publishing Ltd. p. 67. 
  21. ^ a b c Morrison, Spencer P. (2016-12-23). "America's Protectionist Past: The Hidden History Of Trade". National Economics Editorial. Retrieved 2016-12-30. 
  22. ^ Jefferson, Thomas (February 19, 1816). "Letter to Benjamin Austin, Jan 9, 1816". Retrieved December 29, 2016. 
  23. ^ Lind, Matthew. "Free Trade Fallacy". Prospect. Archived from the original on 6 January 2006. Retrieved 3 January 2011. 
  24. ^ William McKinley speech, October 4, 1892 in Boston, MA William McKinley Papers (Library of Congress)
  25. ^ Chambers, J.D. (1961). The Workshop of the World: British Economic history from 1820-1880. London: Oxford University Press. 
  26. ^ Chang (2003), Kicking Away the Ladder, p. 17
  27. ^ Chang (2003), Kicking Away the Ladder, p. 59
  28. ^ Chang (2003), Kicking Away the Ladder, p. 50
  29. ^ Washington, George (January 8, 1790). "First Annual Message to Congress on the State of the Union, January 8, 1790". US Congress. Retrieved July 4, 2016. 
  30. ^ Lincoln, Abraham. “Fragments from a Tariff Discussion 1847.” in the Collected Works of Abraham Lincoln Volume 1, 1809-1865. 
  31. ^ William McKinley speech, Oct. 4, 1892 in Boston, MA William McKinley Papers (Library of Congress)
  32. ^ Roosevelt, Theodore (1902). ""State of the Union Address, 1902."". Retrieved July 4, 2016. 
  33. ^ Bairoch, Paul (1993). Economics and World History: Myths and Paradoxes. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. p. 47. 
  34. ^ DeJong, David (2006). "Tariffs and Growth: an empirical exploration of contingent relationships.". The Review of Economics and Statistics. 88: 625–640. 
  35. ^ Friedman, Milton (1979). Free To Choose. New York: Houghton Mifflin Harcourt Publishing Company. 
  36. ^ a b Ricardo, David (1821). On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. John Murray. p. 7.19. 
  37. ^ Daly, Herman (2007). Ecological Economics and Sustainable Development, Selected Essays of Herman Daly. Northampton MA: Edward Elgar Publishing. 
  38. ^ Krugman, Paul R. (1987). "Is Free Trade Passe?". The Journal of Economic Perspectives. 1 (2): 131–44. doi:10.1257/jep.1.2.131. JSTOR 1942985. 
  39. ^ Krugman, Paul (Jan. 24, 1997). The Accidental Theorist. Slate.
  40. ^ Magee, Stephen P. (1976). International Trade and Distortions In Factor Markets. New York: Marcel-Dekker. 
  41. ^ Krugman, Paul (Mar. 21, 1997). In Praise of Cheap Labor. Slate.
  42. ^ Krugman, Paul (Nov. 21, 1997). A Raspberry for Free Trade. Slate.
  43. ^ "Convictions Opposed to Certain Popular Opinions: The 1903 Anti-Protectionism Letter Supported by 16 British Economists". Econ Journal Watch 7(2): 157–61, May 2010. econjwatch.org
  44. ^ Sicilia, David B. & Cruikshank, Jeffrey L. (2000). The Greenspan Effect, p. 131. New York: McGraw-Hill. ISBN 0-07-134919-7.
  45. ^ DiLorenzo, T. J., ‘Frederic Bastiat (1801–1850): Between the French and Marginalist Revolutions’, accessed at [Ludwig Von Mises Institute] 2012-04-13
  46. ^ "Independent monitoring of policies that affect world trade". Global Trade Alert. Retrieved 2016-12-16. 
  47. ^ Fouda, Regine (October 2012). "Protectionism and Free Trade: A Country's Glory or Doom?" (PDF). International Journal of Trade, Economics and Finance. 5. 3: 351. Retrieved 13 April 2014. .
  48. ^ "A French Roadblock to Free Trade". The New York Times. 2003-08-31. Retrieved 2010-05-22. 
  49. ^ (www.dw.com), Deutsche Welle. "Brussels Warns US on Protectionism - Business - DW.COM - 30.01.2009". 
  50. ^ Independent monitoring of policies that affect world trade. Global Trade Alert. Retrieved on 2013-08-17.
  51. ^ imf.org

External links And Additional Reading[edit]

External links[edit]

Additional Reading[edit]