A minimum wage is the lowest hourly, daily or monthly remuneration that employers may legally pay to workers. Equivalently, it is the lowest wage at which workers may sell their labor. Although minimum wage laws are in effect in many jurisdictions, differences of opinion exist about the benefits and drawbacks of a minimum wage.
Supporters of the minimum wage say that it increases the standard of living of workers, reduces poverty, and forces businesses to be more efficient. Opponents say that if it is high enough to be effective, it increases unemployment, particularly among workers with very low productivity due to inexperience or handicap, thereby harming less skilled workers and possibly excluding some groups from the labor market; additionally it is less effective and more damaging to businesses than other methods of reducing poverty.[1]
The minimum wage has a strong social appeal, rooted in concern about the ability of markets to provide income equity for the least able members of the work force. For some people, the obvious solution to this concern is to redefine the wage structure politically to achieve a socially preferable distribution of income. Thus, minimum wage laws have usually been judged against the criterion of reducing poverty.[2]
Statutory minimum wages were also proposed as a way to control the proliferation of sweat shops in manufacturing industries. The sweat shops employed large numbers of women and young workers, paying them what were considered to be substandard wages. The sweatshop owners were thought to have unfair bargaining power over their workers, and a minimum wage was proposed as a means to make them pay "fairly". Over time, the focus changed to helping people, especially families, become more self sufficient. Today, minimum wage laws affect workers in most low-paid fields of employment.[3]
Although the goals of the minimum wage are widely accepted as proper, there is great disagreement as to whether the minimum wage is effective in attaining its goals. From the time of their introduction, minimum wage laws have been highly controversial politically, and have received much less support from economists than from the general public. Despite decades of experience and economic research, debates about the costs and benefits of minimum wages continue today.[3]
The classic exposition of the minimum wage's shortcomings in reducing poverty was provided by George Stigler in 1946:
- Employment may fall more than in proportion to the wage increase, thereby reducing overall earnings;
- As uncovered sectors of the economy absorb workers released from the covered sectors, the decrease in wages in the uncovered sectors may exceed the increase in wages in the covered ones;
- The impact of the minimum wage on family income distribution may be negative unless the fewer but better jobs are allocated to members of needy families rather than to, for example, teenagers from families not in poverty;
- Forbidding employers to pay less than a legal minimum is equivalent to forbidding workers to sell their labour for less than the minimum wage. The legal restriction that employers cannot pay less than a legislated wage is equivalent to the legal restriction that workers cannot work at all in the protected sector unless they can find employers willing to hire them at that wage.[2]
Direct empirical studies indicate that anti-poverty effects in the U.S. would be quite modest, even if there were no unemployment effects. Very few low-wage workers come from families in poverty. Those primarily affected by minimum wage laws are teenagers and low-skilled adult females who work part time, and any wage rate effects on their income is strictly proportional to the hours of work they are offered. So, if market outcomes for low-skilled families are to be supplemented in a socially satisfactory way, factors other than wage rates must also be considered. Employment opportunities and the factors that limit labor market participation must be considered as well.[2]
First enacted in New Zealand in 1894,[4][5] there is now legislation or binding collective bargaining regarding minimum wage in more than 90% of all countries.[6]
Minimum wage rates vary greatly across many different jurisdictions, not only in setting a particular amount of money (e.g. US$7.25 per hour under U.S. Federal law, $9.04 in the U.S. state of Washington,[7] and £6.08 (for those aged 21+) in the United Kingdom[8]), but also in terms of which pay period (e.g. Russia and China set monthly minimums) or the scope of coverage. Some jurisdictions allow employers to count tips given to their workers as credit towards the minimum wage level. (See also: List of minimum wages by country)
Sometimes a minimum wage exists without a law. Custom and extra-legal pressures from governments or labor unions can produce a de facto minimum wage. So can international public opinion, by pressuring multinational companies to pay Third World workers wages usually found in more industrialized countries. The latter situation in Southeast Asia and Latin America has been publicized in recent years, but it existed with companies in West Africa in the middle of the 20th century.[9] Blanket minimum wage levels for all industries could also be set as a fixed percentage of the GDP per capita or the income tax threshold of the nation.
Among the indicators that might be used to establish an initial minimum wage rate are ones that minimize the loss of jobs while preserving international competitiveness.[10] Among these are general economic conditions as measured by real and nominal gross domestic product; inflation; labor supply and demand; wage levels, distribution and differentials; employment terms; productivity growth; labor costs; business operating costs; the number and trend of bankruptcies; economic freedom rankings; standards of living and the prevailing average wage rate.
In the business sector, concerns include the expected increased cost of doing business, threats to profitability, rising levels of unemployment (and subsequent higher government expenditure on welfare benefits raising tax rates), and the possible knock-on effects to the wages of more experienced workers who might already be earning the new statutory minimum wage, or slightly more.[11]
Among workers and their representatives, political consideration weigh in as labor leaders seek to win support by demanding the highest possible rate. [12] Other concerns include purchasing power, inflation indexing and standardized working hours.
In the United States, the minimum wage promulgated by the Fair Labor Standards Act of 1938 was intentionally set at a high, national level to render low-technology, low-wage factories in the South obsolete.[13]
An analysis of supply and demand of the type shown in introductory mainstream economics textbooks implies that by mandating a price floor above the equilibrium wage, minimum wage laws should cause unemployment.[14][15] This is because a greater number of people are willing to work at the higher wage while a smaller numbers of jobs will be available at the higher wage. Companies can be more selective in those whom they employ thus the least skilled and least experienced will typically be excluded.
According to the model shown in nearly all introductory textbooks on economics, increasing the minimum wage decreases the employment of minimum-wage workers.[16] One such textbook says:
If a higher minimum wage increases the wage rates of unskilled workers above the level that would be established by market forces, the quantity of unskilled workers employed will fall. The minimum wage will price the services of the least productive (and therefore lowest-wage) workers out of the market. ... The direct results of minimum wage legislation are clearly mixed. Some workers, most likely those whose previous wages were closest to the minimum, will enjoy higher wages. This is known as the "ripple effect". The ripple effect shows that when you increase the minimum wage the wages of all others will consequently increase due the need for relativity. (Formby, J., Bishop, J., & Kim, H.. (2010). The Redistributive Effects and Cost-Effectiveness of Increasing the Federal Minimum Wage. Public Finance Review, 38(5), 585. Retrieved April 18, 2012, from ABI/INFORM Global. (Document ID: 2140268271).) Others, particularly those with the lowest prelegislation wage rates, will be unable to find work. They will be pushed into the ranks of the unemployed or out of the labor force. Some argue that by increasing the federal minimum wage, however, the economy will be adversely affected due to small businesses not being able to keep up with the need to subsequently increase all workers wages. (Belman, D., & Wolfson, P.. (2010). The Effect of Legislated Minimum Wage Increases on Employment and Hours: A Dynamic Analysis. Labour, 24(1), 1-25. Retrieved April 18, 2012, from ABI/INFORM Global. (Document ID: 1960232931).) [17]
It illustrates the point with a supply and demand diagram similar to the one below.
Graph showing the
mainstream conception of the labour market
It is assumed that workers are willing to labor for more hours if paid a higher wage. Economists graph this relationship with the wage on the vertical axis and the quantity (hours) of labor supplied on the horizontal axis. Since higher wages increase the quantity supplied, the supply of labor curve is upward sloping, and is shown as a line moving up and to the right.[18]
A firm's cost is a function of the wage rate. It is assumed that the higher the wage, the fewer hours an employer will demand of an employee. This is because, as the wage rate rises, it becomes more expensive for firms to hire workers and so firms hire fewer workers (or hire them for fewer hours). The demand of labor curve is therefore shown as a line moving down and to the right.[18]
Combining the demand and supply curves for labor allows us to examine the effect of the minimum wage. We will start by assuming that the supply and demand curves for labor will not change as a result of raising the minimum wage. This assumption has been questioned.[citation needed] If no minimum wage is in place, workers and employers will continue to adjust the quantity of labor supplied according to price until the quantity of labor demanded is equal to the quantity of labor supplied, reaching equilibrium price, where the supply and demand curves intersect. Minimum wage behaves as a classical price floor on labor. Standard theory says that, if set above the equilibrium price, more labor will be willing to be provided by workers than will be demanded by employers, creating a surplus of labor, i.e., unemployment.[18]
In other words, the simplest and most basic economics says this about commodities like labor (and wheat, for example): Artificially raising the price of the commodity tends to cause the supply of it to increase and the demand for it to lessen. The result is a surplus of the commodity. When there is a wheat surplus, the government buys it. Since the government doesn't hire surplus labor, the labor surplus takes the form of unemployment, which tends to be higher with minimum wage laws than without them.[9]
So the basic theory says that raising the minimum wage helps workers whose wages are raised, and hurts people who are not hired (or lose their jobs) because companies cut back on employment. But proponents of the minimum wage hold that the situation is much more complicated than the basic theory can account for.
One complicating factor is possible monopsony in the labor market, whereby the individual employer has some market power in determining wages paid. Thus it is at least theoretically possible that the minimum wage may boost employment. Though single employer market power is unlikely to exist in most labor markets in the sense of the traditional 'company town,' asymmetric information, imperfect mobility, and the 'personal' element of the labor transaction give some degree of wage-setting power to most firms.[19]
The argument that minimum wages decrease employment is based on a simple supply and demand model of the labor market. A number of economists (for example Pierangelo Garegnani,[20] Robert L. Vienneau,[21] and Arrigo Opocher & Ian Steedman[22]), building on the work of Piero Sraffa, argue that that model, even given all its assumptions, is logically incoherent. Michael Anyadike-Danes and Wyne Godley [23] argue, based on simulation results, that little of the empirical work done with the textbook model constitutes a potentially falsifying test, and, consequently, empirical evidence hardly exists for that model. Graham White [24] argues, partially on the basis of Sraffianism, that the policy of increased labor market flexibility, including the reduction of minimum wages, does not have an "intellectually coherent" argument in economic theory.
Gary Fields, Professor of Labor Economics and Economics at Cornell University, argues that the standard "textbook model" for the minimum wage is "ambiguous", and that the standard theoretical arguments incorrectly measure only a one-sector market. Fields says a two-sector market, where "the self-employed, service workers, and farm workers are typically excluded from minimum-wage coverage… [and with] one sector with minimum-wage coverage and the other without it [and possible mobility between the two]," is the basis for better analysis. Through this model, Fields shows the typical theoretical argument to be ambiguous and says "the predictions derived from the textbook model definitely do not carry over to the two-sector case. Therefore, since a non-covered sector exists nearly everywhere, the predictions of the textbook model simply cannot be relied on."[25]
An alternate view of the labor market has low-wage labor markets characterized as monopsonistic competition wherein buyers (employers) have significantly more market power than do sellers (workers). This monopsony could be a result of intentional collusion between employers, or naturalistic factors such as segmented markets, search costs, information costs, imperfect mobility and the 'personal' element of labor markets. In such a case the diagram above would not yield the quantity of labor clearing and the wage rate. This is because while the upward sloping aggregate labor supply would remain unchanged, instead of using the downward labor demand curve shown in the diagram above, monopsonistic employers would use a steeper downward sloping curve corresponding to marginal expenditures to yield the intersection with the supply curve resulting in a wage rate lower than would be the case under competition. Also, the amount of labor sold would also be lower than the competitive optimal allocation.
Such a case is a type of market failure and results in workers being paid less than their marginal value. Under the monopsonistic assumption, an appropriately set minimum wage could increase both wages and employment, with the optimal level being equal to the marginal productivity of labor.[26] This view emphasizes the role of minimum wages as a market regulation policy akin to antitrust policies, as opposed to an illusory "free lunch" for low-wage workers.
Another reason minimum wage may not affect employment in certain industries is that the demand for the product the employees produce is highly inelastic;[27] For example, if management is forced to increase wages, management can pass on the increase in wage to consumers in the form of higher prices. Since demand for the product is highly inelastic, consumers continue to buy the product at the higher price and so the manager is not forced to lay off workers.
Three other possible reasons minimum wages do not affect employment were suggested by Alan Blinder: higher wages may reduce turnover, and hence training costs; raising the minimum wage may "render moot" the potential problem of recruiting workers at a higher wage than current workers; and minimum wage workers might represent such a small proportion of a business's cost that the increase is too small to matter. He admits that he does not know if these are correct, but argues that "the list demonstrates that one can accept the new empirical findings and still be a card-carrying economist."[28]
Various groups have great ideological, political, financial, and emotional investments in issues surrounding minimum wage laws. For example, agencies that administer the laws have a vested interest in showing that "their" laws do not create unemployment, as do labour unions, whose members' jobs are protected by minimum wage laws. On the other side of the issue, low-wage employers such as restaurants finance the Employment Policies Institute, which has released numerous studies opposing the minimum wage.[29] The presence of these powerful groups and factors means that the debate on the issue is not always based on dispassionate analysis. Additionally, it is extraordinarily difficult to separate the effects of minimum wage from all the other variables that affect employment.[9]
The following table summarizes the arguments made by those for and against minimum wage laws:
- Arguments in favour of Minimum Wage Laws
Supporters of the minimum wage claim it has these effects:
- Increases the standard of living for the poorest and most vulnerable class in society and raises average.[30]
- Motivates and encourages employees to work harder[31]
- Stimulates consumption, by putting more money in the hands of low-income people who spend their entire paychecks.[30]
- Increases the work ethic of those who earn very little, as employers demand more return from the higher cost of hiring these employees.[30]
- Decreases the cost of government social welfare programs by increasing incomes for the lowest-paid.[30]
- Encourages people to join the workforce rather than pursuing money through illegal means, e.g., selling illegal drugs [32][33]
- Encourages efficiency and automation of industry.[34]
- Removes low paying jobs, forcing workers to train for, and move to, higher paying jobs.[35][36]
- Increases technological development. Costly technology that increases business efficiency is more appealing as the price of labour increases.[37]
|
- Arguments against Minimum Wage Laws
Opponents of the minimum wage claim it has these effects:
- As a labor market analogue of political-economic protectionism, it excludes low cost competitors from labor markets and hampers firms in reducing wage costs during trade downturns. This generates various industrial-economic inefficiencies.[38]
- Hurts small business more than large business.[39]
- Reduces quantity demanded of workers, either through a reduction in the number of hours worked by individuals, or through a reduction in the number of jobs.[40][41]
- May cause price inflation as businesses try to compensate by raising the prices of the goods being sold.[42][43]
- Benefits some workers at the expense of the poorest and least productive.[44]
- Can result in the exclusion of certain groups from the labor force.[45]
- Small firms with limited payroll budgets cannot offer their most valuable employees fair and attractive wages above unskilled workers paid the artificially high minimum, and see a rising hurdle-cost of adding workers.[39]
- Is less effective than other methods (e.g. the Earned Income Tax Credit) at reducing poverty, and is more damaging to businesses than those other methods.[46]
- Discourages further education among the poor by enticing people to enter the job market.[46]
- Discriminates against, through pricing out, less qualified workers (including newcomers to the labor market, e.g. young workers) by keeping them from accumulating work experience and qualifications, hence potentially graduating to higher wages later. (This may be a reason why trade unions press for minimum wages, i.e. to protect older workers on the job from the competition of younger, cheaper workers on the job market, for a given level of productivity.)
|
In 2006, the International Labour Organization (ILO)[6] argued that the minimum wage could not be directly linked to unemployment in countries that have suffered job losses. In April 2010, the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD)[47] released a report arguing that countries could alleviate teen unemployment by “lowering the cost of employing low-skilled youth” through a sub-minimum training wage. A study of U.S. states showed that businesses' annual and average payrolls grow faster and employment grew at a faster rate in states with a minimum wage.[48] The study showed a correlation, but did not claim to prove causation.
Although strongly opposed by both the business community and the Conservative Party when introduced in 1999, the minimum wage introduced in the UK is no longer controversial and the Conservatives reversed their opposition in 2000.[49] A review of its effects found no discernible impact on employment levels.[50] However, prices in the minimum wage sector were found to have risen significantly faster than prices in non-minimum wage sectors, most notably in the four years following the implementation of the minimum wage.[51]
Since the introduction of a national minimum wage in the UK in 1999, its effects on employment were subject to extensive research and observation by the Low Pay Commission. The Low Pay Commission found that, rather than make employees redundant, employers have reduced their rate of hiring, reduced staff hours, increased prices, and have found ways to cause current workers to be more productive (especially service companies).[52] Neither trade unions nor employer organizations contest the minimum wage, although the latter had especially done so heavily until 1999.
Economists disagree as to the measurable impact of minimum wages in the 'real world'. This disagreement usually takes the form of competing empirical tests of the elasticities of demand and supply in labor markets and the degree to which markets differ from the efficiency that models of perfect competition predict.
Economists have done empirical studies on numerous aspects of the minimum wage, prominently including:[3]
- Employment effects, the most frequently studied aspect
- Effects on the distribution of wages and earnings among low-paid and higher-paid workers
- Effects on the distribution of incomes among low-income and higher-income families
- Effects on the skills of workers through job training and the deferring of work to acquire education
- Effects on prices and profits
- Effects on on-the-job training
Until the mid-1990s, a strong consensus existed among economists, both conservative and liberal, that the minimum wage reduced employment, especially among younger and low-skill workers.[16] In addition to the basic supply-demand intuition, there were a number of empirical studies that supported this view. For example, Gramlich (1976) found that many of the benefits went to higher income families, and in particular that teenagers were made worse off by the unemployment associated with the minimum wage.[53]
Brown et al. (1983) note that time series studies to that point had found that for a 10 percent increase in the minimum wage, there was a decrease in teenage employment of 1-3 percent. However, for the effect on the teenage unemployment rate, the studies exhibited wider variation in their estimates, from zero to over 3 percent. In contrast to the simple supply/demand figure above, it was commonly found that teenagers withdrew from the labor force in response to the minimum wage, which produced the possibility of equal reductions in the supply as well as the demand for labor at a higher minimum wage and hence no impact on the unemployment rate. Using a variety of specifications of the employment and unemployment equations (using ordinary least squares vs. generalized least squares regression procedures, and linear vs. logarithmic specifications), they found that a 10 percent increase in the minimum wage caused a 1 percent decrease in teenage employment, and no change in the teenage unemployment rate. The study also found a small, but statistically significant, increase in unemployment for adults aged 20–24.[54]
Wellington (1991) updated Brown et al.'s research with data through 1986 to provide new estimates encompassing a period when the real (i.e., inflation-adjusted) value of the minimum wage was declining, because it had not increased since 1981. She found that a 10% increase in the minimum wage decreased the absolute teenage employment by 0.6%, with no effect on the teen or young adult unemployment rates.[55]
Some research suggests that the unemployment effects of small minimum wage increases are dominated by other factors.[56] In Florida, where voters approved an increase in 2004, a follow-up comprehensive study confirms a strong economy with increased employment above previous years in Florida and better than in the U.S. as a whole.[57]
When it comes to on-the-job training, some believe the increase in wages is taken out of training expenses. A 2001 empirical study found that there is "no evidence that minimum wages reduce training, and little evidence that they tend to increase training."[58]
In 1992, the minimum wage in New Jersey increased from $4.25 to $5.05 per hour (an 18.8% increase) while the adjacent state of Pennsylvania remained at $4.25. David Card and Alan Krueger gathered information on fast food restaurants in New Jersey and eastern Pennsylvania in an attempt to see what effect this increase had on employment within New Jersey. Basic economic theory would have implied that relative employment should have decreased in New Jersey. Card and Krueger surveyed employers before the April 1992 New Jersey increase, and again in November–December 1992, asking managers for data on the full-time equivalent staff level of their restaurants both times.[59] Based on data from the employers' responses, the authors concluded that the increase in the minimum wage increased employment in the New Jersey restaurants.[60]
Card and Krueger expanded on this initial article in their 1995 book Myth and Measurement: The New Economics of the Minimum Wage.[61] They argued that the negative employment effects of minimum wage laws are minimal if not non-existent. For example, they look at the 1992 increase in New Jersey's minimum wage, the 1988 rise in California's minimum wage, and the 1990-91 increases in the federal minimum wage. In addition to their own findings, they reanalyzed earlier studies with updated data, generally finding that the older results of a negative employment effect did not hold up in the larger datasets.
Critics, however, argue that their research was flawed.[62] Subsequent attempts to verify the claims requested payroll cards from employers to verify employment, and found that the minimum wage increases were followed by decreases in employment. On the other hand, an assessment of data collected and analyzed by David Neumark and William Wascher did not initially contradict the Card/Krueger results,[63] but in a later edited version they found that the same general sample set did increase unemployment. The 18.8% wage hike resulted in "[statistically] insignificant—although almost always negative" employment effects.[64]
Another possible explanation for why the current minimum wage laws may not affect unemployment in the United States is that the minimum wage is set close to the equilibrium point for low and unskilled workers. Thus in the absence of the minimum wage law unskilled workers would be paid approximately the same amount. However, an increase above this equilibrium point could likely bring about increased unemployment for the low and unskilled workers.[18]
Some leading economists such as Kevin M. Murphy and Nobel laureate Gary Becker do not accept the Card/Krueger results,[65] while some others, like Nobel laureates Paul Krugman[66] and Joseph Stiglitz, accept them.[67][68]
According to economists Donald Deere (Texas A&M), Kevin Murphy (University of Chicago), and Finis Welch (Texas A&M), Card and Krueger's conclusions are contradicted by "common sense and past research". They conclude:[69]
Each of the four studies examines a different piece of the minimum wage/employment relationship. Three of them consider a single state, and two of them look at only a handful of firms in one industry. From these isolated findings Card and Krueger paint a big picture wherein increased minimum wages do not decrease, and may increase, employment. Our view is that there is something wrong with this picture. Artificial increases in the price of unskilled laborers inevitably lead to their reduced employment; the conventional wisdom remains intact.
Nobel laureate James M. Buchanan responded to the Card and Krueger study in the Wall Street Journal, arguing:[70]
...no self-respecting economist would claim that increases in the minimum wage increase employment. Such a claim, if seriously advanced, becomes equivalent to a denial that there is even minimum scientific content in economics, and that, in consequence, economists can do nothing but write as advocates for ideological interests. Fortunately, only a handful of economists are willing to throw over the teaching of two centuries; we have not yet become a bevy of camp-following whores.
Alan Krueger responded in The Washington Post:[71]
More was at stake here than the minimum wage – the methodology of public policy analysis was also at issue. Some economists, such as James Buchanan, have simply rejected the notion that their view of economic theory possibly could be proved wrong by data.
Nobel laureate Paul Krugman, has argued in favour of the Card and Krueger result, stating that Card and Krueger;[72]
... found no evidence that minimum wage increases in the range that the United States has experiences led to job losses. Their work has been attacked because it seems to contradict Econ 101 and because it was ideologically disturbing to many. Yet it has stood up very well to repeated challenges, and new cases confirming its results keep coming in.
In a 2008 book, David Neumark and William L. Wascher described their analysis of studies on the minimum wage, from several countries covering a period of over 50 years (but primarily from the 1990s onward).[3] According to the Neumark and Wascher, a large majority of the studies show negative effects for the minimum wage; those showing positive effects are few, questionable, and disproportionately discussed.
Based on the published studies they considered, Neumark and Wascher conclude that the minimum wage is not good social policy. They emphasize three conclusions: First, while acknowledging Card and Krueger, they found that studies since the early 1990s have strongly pointed to a "reduction in employment opportunities for low-skilled and directly affected workers." Second, they found some evidence that the minimum wage is harmful to poverty-stricken families, and "virtually no evidence" that it helps them. Third, they found that the minimum wage lowers adult wages of young workers who encounter it, by reducing their ultimate level of education.
Several researchers have conducted statistical meta-analyses of the employment effects of the minimum wage. In 1995, Card and Krueger analyzed 14 earlier time-series studies on minimum wages and concluded that there was clear evidence of publication bias (in favor of studies that found a statistically significant negative employment effect). They point out that later studies, which had more data and lower standard errors, did not show the expected increase in t-statistic (almost all the studies had a t-statistic of about two, just above the level of statistical significance at the .05 level).[73] Though a serious methodological indictment, opponents of the minimum wage largely ignored this issue; as Thomas C. Leonard noted, "The silence is fairly deafening."[74]
In 2005, T.D. Stanley showed that Card and Krueger's results could signify either publication bias or the absence of a minimum wage effect. However, using a different methodology, Stanley concludes that there is evidence of publication bias, and that correction of this bias shows no relationship between the minimum wage and unemployment.[75] In 2008, Hristos Doucouliagos and T.D. Stanley conducted a similar meta-analysis of 64 U.S. studies on dis-employment effects and concluded that Card and Krueger's initial claim of publication bias is still correct. Moreover, they concluded, "Once this publication selection is corrected, little or no evidence of a negative association between minimum wages and employment remains."[76]
Until the 1990s, economists generally agreed that raising the minimum wage reduced employment. This consensus was weakened when some well-publicized empirical studies showed the opposite, although others confirmed the original view. Today's consensus, if one exists, is that increasing the minimum wage has, at worst, minor negative effects.[77]
According to a 1978 article in the American Economic Review, 90 percent of the economists surveyed agreed that the minimum wage increases unemployment among low-skilled workers.[78]
A 1992 survey by published in the same journal revealed 79% of economists in agreement that a minimum wage increases unemployment among young and unskilled workers.[79]
A 2000 survey by Dan Fuller and Doris Geide-Stevenson reports that of a sample of 308 American Economic Association economists, 45.6% fully agreed with the statement, "a minimum wage increases unemployment among young and unskilled workers", 27.9% agreed with provisos, and 26.5% disagreed. The authors of this study also reweighted data from a 1990 sample to show that at that time 62.4% of academic economists agreed with the statement above, while 19.5% agreed with provisos and 17.5% disagreed. They state that the reduction on consensus on this question is "likely" due to the Card and Krueger research and subsequent debate.[80]
A similar survey in 2006 by Robert Whaples polled PhD members of the American Economic Association. Whaples found that 37.7% of respondents supported an increase in the minimum wage, 14.3% wanted it kept at the current level, 1.3% wanted it decreased, and 46.8% wanted it completely eliminated.[81]
Surveys of labor economists have found a sharp split on the minimum wage. Fuchs et al. (1998) polled labor economists at the top 40 research universities in the United States on a variety of questions in the summer of 1996. Their 65 respondents were nearly evenly divided when asked if the minimum wage should be increased. They argued that the different policy views were not related to views on whether raising the minimum wage would reduce teen employment (the median economist said there would be a reduction of 1%), but on value differences such as income redistribution.[82] Daniel B. Klein and Stewart Dompe conclude, on the basis of previous surveys, "the average level of support for the minimum wage is somewhat higher among labor economists than among AEA members."[83]
In 2007, Klein and Dompe conducted a non-anonymous survey of supporters of the minimum wage who had signed the "Raise the Minimum Wage" statement published by the Economic Policy Institute. They found that a majority signed on the grounds that it transferred income from employers to workers, or equalized bargaining power between them in the labor market. In addition, a majority considered disemployment to be a moderate potential drawback to the increase they supported.[84]
Economists and other political commentators have proposed alternatives to the minimum wage. They argue that these alternatives may address the issue of poverty better than a minimum wage, as it would benefit a broader population of low wage earners, not cause any unemployment, and distribute the costs widely rather than concentrating it on employers of low wage workers.
A basic income (or negative income tax) is a system of social security, that periodically provides each citizen with a sum of money that is sufficient to live on. Except for citizenship, a basic income is entirely unconditional. There is no means test, and the richest as well as the poorest citizens would receive it. A basic income is often proposed in the form of a citizen's dividend (a transfer payment from the government). Proponents argue that a basic income that is based on a broad tax base, would be more economically efficient, as the minimum wage effectively imposes a high marginal tax on employers, causing losses in efficiency.
In 1968 James Tobin, Paul Samuelson, John Kenneth Galbraith and another 1,200 economists signed a document calling for the US Congress to introduce in that year a system of income guarantees and supplements.[85] Both Tobin and Samuelson have also come out against the minimum wage.[86] In the 1972 presidential campaign, Senator George McGovern called for a 'demogrant' that was very similar to a basic income.[87]
Winners of the Nobel Prize in Economics that fully support a basic income include Herbert A. Simon,[88] Friedrich Hayek,[89] Robert Solow,[88] Milton Friedman,[90] Jan Tinbergen,[88] James Tobin[85][91][92] and James Meade.[88]
A guaranteed minimum income is another proposed system of social welfare provision. It is similar to a basic income or negative income tax system, except that it is normally conditional and subject to a means test. Some proposals also stipulate a willingness to participate in the labor market, or a willingness to perform community services.[citation needed]
A refundable tax credit is a mechanism whereby the tax system can reduce the tax owed by a household to below zero, and result in a net payment to the taxpayer beyond their own payments into the tax system. Examples of refundable tax credits include the earned income tax credit and the additional child tax credit in the U.S., and working tax credits and child tax credits in the UK. Such a system is slightly different from a negative income tax, in that the refundable tax credit is usually only paid to households that have earned at least some income.
In the United States, earned income tax credit rates, also known as EITC or EIC, vary by state—some are refundable while other states do not allow a refundable tax credit.[93] The federal EITC program has been expanded by a number of presidents including Jimmy Carter, Ronald Reagan, George H.W. Bush, and Bill Clinton.[94] In 1986, President Reagan described the EITC as "the best anti poverty, the best pro-family, the best job creation measure to come out of Congress." [95] The ability of the earned income tax credit to deliver larger monetary benefits to poor workers than an increase in the minimum wage and at a lower cost to society was documented in a 2007 report by the Congressional Budget Office.[96]
Germany,[97] Italy, Sweden and Denmark are examples of developed nations where there is no minimum wage that is required by legislation. Instead, minimum wage standards in different sectors are set by collective bargaining.[citation needed]
- ^ Black, John (2003-09-18). Oxford Dictionary of Economics. Oxford University Press, USA. p. 300. http://www.amazon.com/dp/0198607679.
- ^ a b c Eatwell, John, Ed.; Murray Milgate, Peter Newman (1987). The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics. London: The Macmillan Press Limited. pp. 476–478. ISBN 0-333-37235-2.
- ^ a b c d Neumark, David; William L. Wascher (2008). Minimum Wages. Cambridge, Massachusetts: The MIT Press. ISBN 978-0-262-14102-4. http://mitpress.mit.edu/catalog/item/default.asp?ttype=2&tid=11659.
- ^ "Minimum wage encyclopedia topics | Reference.com". 74.125.153.132. http://74.125.153.132/search?q=cache:BGJadOmw1JAJ:www.reference.com/browse/minimum%2Bwage+zealand+%22first+minimum+wage+law%22+1894&cd=2&hl=en&ct=clnk. Retrieved 2010-07-29.
- ^ "The best anti-poverty program we have? - Free Online Library". 74.125.153.132. http://74.125.153.132/search?q=cache:E83FNT8k_-UJ:www.thefreelibrary.com/The%2Bbest%2Banti-poverty%2Bprogram%2Bwe%2Bhave%253F-a0203335454+zealand+%22first+minimum+wage+law%22+1894&cd=4&hl=en&ct=clnk. Retrieved 2010-07-29.
- ^ a b "ILO 2006: Minimum wages policy (PDF)". Ilo.org. http://www.ilo.org/public/english/protection/condtrav/pdf/infosheets/w-1.pdf. Retrieved 2012-03-01.
- ^ "Washington is first state with $9 minimum wage". MarketWatch. http://www.marketwatch.com/story/washington-is-first-state-with-9-minimum-wage-2012-01-01. Retrieved 2012-03-01.
- ^ "Minimum wage up by 15p to £6.08", BBC News, http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/business-13000171#b
- ^ a b c Sowell, Thomas (2007-04-02). Basic Economics (3rd Edition): A Common Sense Guide to the Economy. New York: Basic Books. ISBN 0-465-00260-9. http://www.amazon.com/dp/0465002609. Minimum Wage Laws are covered on pages 210-221. The full text of an essentially identical section from a previous edition can be found at page 163 HERE
- ^ Provisional Minimum Wage Commission: Preliminary Views on a Bask of Indicators, Other Relevant Considerations and Impact Assessment, Provisional Minimum Wage Commission, Hong Kong Special Administrative Region Government, [1]
- ^ Setting the Initial Statutory Minimum Wage Rate, submission to government by the Hong Kong General Chamber of Commerce.
- ^ Li, Joseph, “Minimum wage legislation for all sectors,” China Daily October 16, 2008 [2], “Hong Kong sets Minimum Wage – What one Singaporean thinks,” Speaker’s Corner, SG Forums, November 5, 2010 [3]
- ^ Berstein, David E., & Leonard, Thomas C., Excluding Unfit Workers: Social Control Versus Social Justice in the Age of Economic Reform, Law and Contemporary Problems, Vol. 72, No. 3, 2009 [4]
- ^ McConnell, C.R. and S.L. Brue, Economics, Irwin-McGraw Hill, 1999, 14th ed., p. 594.
- ^ Gwartney, J.D., R.L. Stroup, R.S. Sobel, and D.A. Macpherson, Economics: Private and Public Choice, Thomson South-Western, 2003, 10th ed., p. 97.
- ^ a b David Card and Alan B. Krueger, Myth and Measurement: The New Economics of the Minimum Wage, Princeton University Press, 1995, pp. 1, 6-7.
- ^ Gwartney, James D.; Richard L. Stroup. Economics: Private and Public Choice. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich. pp. 559–562. ISBN 0-15-518880-1.
- ^ a b c d Ehrenberg, R. and Smith, R. "Modern labor economics: theory and public policy", HarperCollins, 1994, 5th ed.
- ^ William M. Boal and Michael R. Ransom, "Monopsony in the Labor Market", Journal of Economic Literature, V.35, March, pgs.86-112 [5]
- ^ P. Garegnani, "Heterogeneous Capital, the Production Function and the Theory of Distribution", Review of Economic Studies, V. 37, N. 3 (July 1970): 407-436
- ^ Robert L. Vienneau, "On Labour Demand and Equilibria of the Firm", Manchester School, V. 73, N. 5 (September 2005): 612-619
- ^ Arrigo Opocher and Ian Steedman, "Input Price-Input Quantity Relations and the Numeraire", Cambridge Journal of Economics, V. 3 (2009): 937-948
- ^ Michael Anyadike-Danes and Wyne Godley, "Real Wages and Employment: A Sceptical View of Some Recent Empirical Work", Machester School, V. 62, N. 2 (June 1989): 172-187
- ^ Graham White, "The Poverty of Conventional Economic Wisdom and the Search for Alternative Economic and Social Policies", The Drawing Board: An Australian Review of Public Affairs, V. 2, N. 2 (November 2001): 67-87
- ^ Gary Fields, "The Unemployment Effects of Minimum Wages," International Journal of Manpower, Vol. 15, issue 2 (1994), pp. 74-81.
- ^ Manning, Alan (2003). Monopsony in motion: Imperfect Competition in Labor Markets. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. ISBN 0-691-11312-2.
- ^ Gillespie, Andrew (2007). Foundations of Economics. Oxford University Press. p. 240.
- ^ Alan S. Blinder, "The $5.15 Question," The New York Times, 23 May 1996, p. A29.
- ^ Harry Bernstein, "Troubling Facts on Employment," Los Angeles Times, September 15, 1992, p. D3; Eric Engquist, "Health Bill Fight Nears Showdown," Crain's New York Business, May 15, 2006, p. 1.
- ^ a b c d Real Value of the Minimum Wage[dead link]
- ^ Richard B. Freeman (1994). Minimum Wages – Again!. International Journal of Manpower.
- ^ "Youth Crime and the Minimum Wage by Andrew Kallem :: SSRN". Papers.ssrn.com. http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=545382. Retrieved 2011-10-05.
- ^ "Crime and work: What we can learn from the low-wage labor market | Economic Policy Institute". Epi.org. 2000-07-01. http://www.epi.org/publications/entry/books_crimeandwork/. Retrieved 2011-10-05.
- ^ Bernard Semmel, Imperialism and Social Reform: English Social-Imperial Thought 1895-1914 (London: Allen and Unwin, 1960), p. 63.
- ^ "ITIF Report Shows Self-service Technology a New Force in Economic Life | The Information Technology & Innovation Foundation". Itif.org. 2010-04-14. http://www.itif.org/pressrelease/itif-report-shows-self-service-technology-new-force-economic-life. Retrieved 2011-10-05.
- ^ "Technology and Labor Regulations 1" (PDF). http://iis-db.stanford.edu/evnts/4651/TechnologyandLaborRegulations.pdf. Retrieved 2012-03-01.
- ^ "Minimum Wages in canada : theory, evidence and policy". Hrsdc.gc.ca. 2008-03-07. http://www.hrsdc.gc.ca/eng/labour/employment_standards/fls/research/research11/page03.shtml. Retrieved 2011-10-05.
- ^ Abbott, Lewis F. Statutory Minimum Wage Controls: A Critical Review of their Effects on Labour Markets, Employment, and Incomes. ISR Publications, Manchester UK, 2nd. edn. 2000. ISBN 978-0-906321-22-5. [6]
- ^ a b Llewellyn H. Rockwell Jr. (2005-10-28). "Wal-Mart Warms to the State - Mises Institute". Mises.org. http://www.mises.org/story/1950. Retrieved 2011-10-05.
- ^ Tupy, Marian L. Minimum Interference, National Review Online, May 14, 2004
- ^ "The Wages of Politics". Wall Street Journal. http://www.opinionjournal.com/weekend/hottopic/?id=110009232.
- ^ Messmore, Ryan. "Increasing the Mandated Minimum Wage: Who Pays the Price?". Heritage.org. http://www.heritage.org/Research/Labor/BG1162.cfm. Retrieved 2011-10-05.
- ^ Art Carden. "Why Wal-Mart Matters - Mises Institute". Mises.org. http://www.mises.org/story/2377. Retrieved 2011-10-05.
- ^ "Will have only negative effects on the distribution of economic justice. Minimum-wage legislation, by its very nature, benefits some at the expense of the least experienced, least productive, and poorest workers." (Cato)
- ^ Williams, Walter (1989). South Africa's War Against Capitalism. New York: Praeger. ISBN 0-275-93179-X.
- ^ a b A blunt instrument, The Economist, October 26, 2006 (English)
- ^ Scarpetta, Stephano, Anne Sonnet and Thomas Manfredi,Rising Youth Unemployment During The Crisis: How To Prevent Negative Long-Term Consequences on a Generation?, 14 April 2010 (read-only PDF)
- ^ Fiscal Policy Institute, "States with Minimum Wages Above the Federal Level have had Faster Small Business and Retail Job Growth," March 30, 2006.
- ^ "National Minimum Wage". politics.co.uk. Archived from the original on December 1, 2007. http://web.archive.org/web/20071201162434/http://www.politics.co.uk/issue-briefs/economy/employment/national-minimum-wage/national-minimum-wage-$366581.htm. Retrieved 2007-12-29.
- ^ Metcalf, David (April 2007). "Why Has the British National Minimum Wage Had Little or No Impact on Employment?". http://ideas.repec.org/p/cep/cepdps/dp0781.html.
- ^ Wadsworth, Jonathan (September 2009). "Did the National Minimum Wage Affect UK Prices". ftp://repec.iza.org/RePEc/Discussionpaper/dp4433.pdf.
- ^ Low Pay Commission (2005). National Minimum Wage - Low Pay Commission Report 2005
- ^ Edward M. Gramlich, "Impact of Minimum Wages on Other Wages, Employment, and Family Incomes," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Volume 1976, number 2, pp. 409-461.)
- ^ Charles Brown, Curtis Gilroy, and Andrew Kohen "Time Series Evidence on the Effect of the Minimum Wage on Youth Employment and Unemployment," The Journal of Human Resources, Volume 18, no. 1 (Winter 1983), pp. 3-31.
- ^ Alison J. Wellington, "Effects of the Minimum Wage on the Employment Status of Youths: An Update," Journal of Human Resources, Volume 26, no. 1 (Winter 1991), pp. 27-46.
- ^ "Minimum wage trends: Understanding past and contemporary research | Economic Policy Institute". Epi.org. http://www.epi.org/content.cfm/bp178. Retrieved 2011-10-05.
- ^ [7][dead link]
- ^ Acemoglu, Daron & Pischke, Jörn-Steffen (2001-11-05). "Minimum Wages and On-the-Job Training". Ideas.repec.org. http://ideas.repec.org/p/iza/izadps/dp384.html. Retrieved 2011-10-05.
- ^ David Card and Alan B. Krueger, "Minimum Wages and Employment: A Case Study of the Fast-Food Industry in New Jersey and Pennsylvania," American Economic Review, Volume 84, no. 4 (September 1994), pp. 774-775.
- ^ p. 792.
- ^ ISBN 0-691-04823-1
- ^ "Myth and Measurement: The New Economics of the Minimum Wage". Cato Institute. April 22, 2006. http://www.cato.org/pubs/journal/cj15n1-8.html.
- ^ [8][dead link]
- ^ Neumark & Wascher, American Economic Review, Volume 90 No. 5.
- ^ Becker, Gary (1995-03-06). "IT'S SIMPLE: HIKE THE MINIMUM WAGE, AND YOU PUT PEOPLE OUT OF WORK". BusinessWeek. http://www.businessweek.com/archives/1995/b341430.arc.htm. Retrieved 2009-07-09.
- ^ Paul Krugman, The conscience of a liberal (W.W. Norton & Co., 2007)
- ^ Joseph Stiglitz. Employment, social justice and societal well-being, International Labour Review, 141 (1-2), p. 9 - 29.
- ^ Economic Policy Institute. Hundreds of Leading Economists Say: Raise the Minimum Wage
- ^ Sense and Nonsense on the Minimum Wage[dead link]
- ^ "Minimum wage addendum". Wall Street Journal: pp. A20. 1996-04-25.
- ^ Alan Krueger, "Test Case for the Labor Market," The Washington Post, September 2, 1996, p. A23.
- ^ Paul Krugman, The Conscience of a Liberal, W.W. Norton, 2007, p. 261
- ^ David Card and Alan B. Krueger, "Time-series minimum-wage studies: a meta-analysis," American Economic Review 85: 238-243 (1995).
- ^ Thomas C. Leonard, "The Very Idea of Applying Economics: The Modern Minimum-Wage Controversy and its Antecedents," History of Political Economy 32 (1), p. 139 (2000).
- ^ T.D. Stanley, "Beyond Publication Bias", Journal of Economic Surveys, Vol. 19, no. 3 (2005), pp. 322-327.
- ^ Hristos Doucouliagos and T.D. Stanley, "Publication Bias in Minimum-Wage Research? A Meta-Regression Analysis," British Journal of Industrial Relations, 2008.
- ^ "A Blunt Instrument; The Minimum Wage," The Economist, October 28, 2006.
- ^ Kearl, J. R., et al., “A Confusion of Economists?” American Economic Review 69 (1979): 28–37.
- ^ Alston, Richard M.; J. R. Kearl, Michael B. Vaughn (May 1992). "Is There a Consensus Among Economists in the 1990's". American Economic Review. http://academic.research.microsoft.com/Paper/3280005.
- ^ Fuller, Dan; Geide-Stevenson, Doris (2003). "Consensus Among Economists: Revisited" (PDF). Journal of Economic Education 34 (4): 369–387. DOI:10.1080/00220480309595230. http://www.indiana.edu/~econed/pdffiles/fall03/fuller.pdf.
- ^ Robert Whaples (2006) "Do Economists Agree on Anything? Yes!," The Economists' Voice: Vol. 3 : Iss. 9, Article 1.
- ^ Victor R. Fuchs, Alan B. Krueger, and James M. Poterba, "Economists' Views About Parameters, Values, and Policies: Survey Results in Labor and Public Economics," Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 36, no. 3 (September 1998), pp. 1387-1425.
- ^ Klein, Daniel and Stewart Dompe. "Reasons for Supporting the Minimum Wage: Asking Signatories of the "Raise the Minimum Wage" Statement" (January 2007), p. 133.
- ^ Klein, Daniel and Stewart Dompe. "Reasons for Supporting the Minimum Wage: Asking Signatories of the "Raise the Minimum Wage" Statement" (January 2007). [9]
- ^ a b Steensland, Brian (2007). The failed welfare revolution. Princeton University Press. pp. 70–78. ISBN 0-691-12714-X, 9780691127149.
- ^ Emerson Schmidt, "Union Power and the Public Interest", EP Dutton, 1980 as cited in [10]
- ^ White, Theodore H. The Making of the President 1972. Antheneum Publishers. 1973. pp. 17–20. ISBN 0-689-10553-3, pg. 127
- ^ a b c d Guy Standing (2005). "1. About Time: Basic Income Security As A Right". In Guy Standing. Promoting Income Security as a Right: Europe and North America (2nd ed.). London: Anthem Press. p. 18. ISBN 978-1-84331-174-4. "Among those who have become convinced of the virtues of the basic income approach are several Nobel Prize-winning economists of surprisingly diverse political convictions: Milton Friedman, Herbert Simon, Robert Solow, Jan Tinbergen and James Tobin (besides, of course, James Meade who was an advocate from his younger days)."
- ^ Hayek, Friedrich (1973). Law, Legislation and Liberty: A New Statement of the Liberal Principles of Justice and Political Economy. 2. Routledge. p. 87. ISBN 0-7100-8403-X.
- ^ Friedman, Milton; Rose Friedman (1990). Free to Choose: A Personal Statement. Harcourt. pp. 120–3. ISBN 0-15-633460-7.
- ^ "Is a Negative Income Tax Practical?", James Tobin, Joseph A. Pechman, and Peter M. Mieszkowski, Yale Law Journal 77 (1967): 1-27.
- ^ Fettig, David (2011 [last update]). "Interview with James Tobin - The Region - Publications & Papers | The Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis". minneapolisfed.org. http://www.minneapolisfed.org/publications_papers/pub_display.cfm?id=3649. Retrieved 25 October 2011. "I would pursue my recommendations of years ago for a negative income tax."
- ^ "50 State Resources Map on State EITCs". The Hatcher Group. http://www.stateeitc.com/map/index.asp. Retrieved 2010-06-16.
- ^ "New Research Findings on the Effects of the Earned Income Tax Credit". Center on Budget and Policy Priorities. http://www.cbpp.org/cms/index.cfm?fa=view&id=1649. Retrieved 2010-06-30.
- ^ "Tax Reform and Poverty". Center on Budget and Policy Priorities. http://www.cbpp.org/cms/index.cfm?fa=view&id=134. Retrieved 2010-06-30.
- ^ "Consequences of an increase in the minimum wage and expansions in the earned income tax credit." (PDF). Congressional Budget Office. http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/77xx/doc7721/01-09-MinimumWageEITC.pdf. Retrieved 2008-07-25.
- ^ "Minimum wages only in some economic branches in Germany". Statistisches Bundesamt. http://www.destatis.de/jetspeed/portal/cms/Sites/destatis/Internet/EN/Content/Statistics/VerdiensteArbeitskosten/Tarifverdienste/Mindestloehne/AktuellD,templateId=renderPrint.psml. Retrieved 2010-05-09. [dead link]
- Support
- Opposed