Joseph Eugene Stiglitz, ForMemRS, FBA, (born February 9, 1943) is an American economist and a professor at Columbia University. He is a recipient of the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences (2001) and the John Bates Clark Medal (1979). He is also the former Senior Vice President and Chief Economist of the World Bank. He is known for his critical view of the management of globalization, free-market economists (whom he calls "free market fundamentalists") and some international institutions like the International Monetary Fund and the World Bank.
In 2000, Stiglitz founded the Initiative for Policy Dialogue (IPD), a think tank on international development based at Columbia University. Since 2001, he has been a member of the Columbia faculty, and has been a University Professor since 2003. He also chairs the University of Manchester's Brooks World Poverty Institute and is a member of the Pontifical Academy of Social Sciences. Stiglitz is also an honorary professor at Tsinghua University School of Public Policy and Management and a member of the Executive and Supervisory Committee (ESC) of CERGE-EI. Stiglitz is one of the most frequently cited economists in the world.
Biography
Stiglitz was born in
Gary,
Indiana, to
Jewish parents, Charlotte and Nathaniel Stiglitz. From 1960 to 1963, he studied at
Amherst College, where he was a highly active member of the debate team and President of the Student Government. He went to the
Massachusetts Institute of Technology (MIT) for his fourth year as an undergraduate, where he later pursued graduate work. His undergraduate degree was awarded from Amherst College. From 1965 to 1966, he moved to the
University of Chicago to do research under
Hirofumi Uzawa who had received an
NSF grant. He studied for his PhD from MIT from 1966 to 1967, during which time he also held an MIT assistant professorship. The particular style of MIT economics suited him well - simple and concrete models, directed at answering important and relevant questions. From 1966 to 1970 he was a research fellow at the
University of Cambridge: he arrived at
Fitzwilliam House as a
Fulbright Scholar in 1965 and then won a Tapp Junior Research Fellowship at
Gonville and Caius College. In subsequent years, he held academic positions at
Yale (1970–1974),
Stanford (1974–1976, 1988–2001),
Oxford (1976–1979), and
Princeton (1979–1988). Stiglitz is now a Professor at
Columbia University, with appointments at the
Business School, the Department of
Economics and the
School of International and Public Affairs (SIPA), and is editor of ''
The Economists' Voice'' journal with
J. Bradford DeLong and
Aaron Edlin. He also gives classes for a double-degree program between
Sciences Po Paris and
Ecole Polytechnique in 'Economics and Public Policy'. As of 2005 he chairs The Brooks World Poverty Institute at the
University of Manchester. Stiglitz is a
New-Keynesian economist.
In addition to making numerous influential contributions to microeconomics, Stiglitz has played a number of policy roles. He served in the Clinton Administration as the chair of the President's Council of Economic Advisors (1995 – 1997). At the World Bank, he served as Senior Vice President and Chief Economist (1997 – 2000), in the time when unprecedented protest against international economic organizations started, most prominently with the Seattle WTO meeting of 1999. He was fired by the World Bank for expressing dissent with its policies. He was a lead author for the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change.
He is a member of Collegium International, an organization of leaders with political, scientific, and ethical expertise whose goal is to provide new approaches in overcoming the obstacles in the way of a peaceful, socially just and an economically sustainable world. He is also a member of the scientific committee of the Fundacion IDEAS, a Spanish think tank.
Stiglitz has advised American President Barack Obama, but has also been sharply critical of the Obama Administration's financial-industry rescue plan. Stiglitz said that whoever designed the Obama administration's bank rescue plan is "either in the pocket of the banks or they’re incompetent."
In October 2008 he was asked by the President of UN's General Assembly to chair a commission entrusted with drafting a report on the reasons for and solutions to the financial crisis. In response, the commission produced the Stiglitz Report.
On July 25, 2011, Stiglitz participated to the "I Foro Social del 15M" organized in Madrid (Spain) expressing his support to the 2011 Spanish protests.
Contributions to economics
Information asymmetry
Stiglitz's most famous research was on
screening, a technique used by one economic agent to extract otherwise private information from another. It was for this contribution to the theory of
information asymmetry that he shared the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics in 2001 "for laying the foundations for
the theory of markets with asymmetric information" with
George A. Akerlof and
A. Michael Spence.
Before the advent of models of imperfect and asymmetric information, the traditional neoclassical economics literature had assumed that markets are efficient except for some limited and well defined market failures. More recent work by Stiglitz and others reversed that presumption, to assert that it is only under exceptional circumstances that markets are efficient. Stiglitz has shown (together with Bruce Greenwald) that "whenever markets are incomplete and/or information is imperfect (which are true in virtually all economies), even competitive market allocation is not constrained Pareto efficient". In other words, they addressed "the problem of determining when tax interventions are Pareto-improving. The approach indicates that such tax interventions almost always exist and that equilibria in situations of imperfect information are rarely constrained Pareto optima." Although these conclusions and the pervasiveness of market failures do not necessarily warrant the state intervening broadly in the economy, it makes clear that the "optimal" range of government recommendable interventions is definitely much larger than the traditional "market failure" school recognizes. For Stiglitz, there is no such thing as an invisible hand. According to Stiglitz:
In the opening remarks for his prize acceptance "Aula Magna", Stiglitz said:
In an interview in 2007, Stiglitz explained further:
Efficiency wages: the Shapiro-Stiglitz model
Stiglitz also did research on
efficiency wages, and helped create what became known as the ''"Shapiro-Stiglitz model"'' to explain why there is
unemployment even in equilibrium, why wages are not bid down sufficiently by job seekers (in the absence of minimum wages) so that everyone who wants a job finds one, and to question whether the
neoclassical paradigm could explain involuntary unemployment. The answer to these puzzles was proposed by
Shapiro and Stiglitz in 1984: "Unemployment is driven by the information structure of employment". Two basic observations undergird their analysis:
# Unlike other forms of capital, humans can choose their level of effort.
# It is costly for firms to determine how much effort workers are exerting.
A full description of this model can be found at the links provided. Some key implications of this model are:
# Wages do not fall enough during recessions to prevent unemployment from rising. If the demand for labour falls, this lowers wages. But because wages have fallen, the probability of 'shirking' (workers not exerting effort) has risen. If employment levels are to be maintained, through a sufficient lowering of wages, workers will be less productive than before through the shirking effect. As a consequence, in the model wages do not fall enough to maintain employment levels at the previous state, because firms want to avoid excessive shirking by their workers. So, unemployment must rise during recessions, because wages are kept 'too high'.
# Possible corollary: Wage sluggishness. Moving from one private cost of hiring to another private cost of hiring will require each firm to repeatedly re-optimize wages in response to shifting unemployment rate. Firms cannot cut wages until unemployment rises sufficiently (a coordination problem).
The outcome is never Pareto efficient.
# Each firm employs too few workers because it faces private cost of hiring rather than the social cost — which is equal to and in all cases. This means that firms do not "internalize" the "external" cost of unemployment - they do not factor how large-scale unemployment harms society when assessing their own costs. This leads to a negative externality as marginal social cost exceeds the firm's marginal cost (MSC = Firm's Private Marginal Cost + Marginal External Cost of increased social unemployment)
# There are also negative externalities. Each firm increases the asset value of unemployment for all other firms by hiring. But the first problem clearly dominates since the 'natural rate of unemployment' is always too high.
Some possible practical implications of Stiglitz theorems
While the mathematical validity of Stiglitz ''et al.'' theorems are not in question, their practical implications in
political economy and their application in real life
economic policies have been subject to considerable disagreement and debate. Stiglitz himself seems to be continuously adapting his own political-economic discourse, as we can see from the evolution in his positions as initially stated in ''Whither Socialism?'' (1994) to his own new positions held on his most recent publications.
::Once incomplete and imperfect information are introduced, Chicago-school defenders of the market system cannot sustain descriptive claims of the Pareto efficiency of the real world. Thus, Stiglitz's use of rational-expectations equilibrium assumptions to achieve a more realistic understanding of capitalism than is usual among rational-expectations theorists leads, paradoxically, to the conclusion that capitalism deviates from the model in a way that justifies state action—socialism—as a remedy.
::The effect of Stiglitz's influence is to make economics even more presumptively interventionist than Samuelson preferred. Samuelson treated market failure as the exception to the general rule of efficient markets. But the Greenwald-Stiglitz theorem posits market failure as the norm, establishing "that government could potentially almost always improve upon the market's resource allocation." And the Sappington-Stiglitz theorem "establishes that an ideal government could do better running an enterprise itself than it could through privatization" (Stiglitz 1994, 179).
The objections to the wide adoption of these positions suggested by Stiglitz's discoveries do not come from economics itself but mostly from political scientists and are in the fields of sociology. As David L. Prychitko discusses in his "critique" to ''Whither Socialism?'' (see below), although Stiglitz's main economic insight seems generally correct, it still leaves open great constitutional questions such as how the coercive institutions of the government should be constrained and what the relation is between the government and civil society.
Politics
Clinton administration, 1993 - 1997
Stiglitz joined the
Clinton Administration in 1993, serving first as a member during 1993-1995, and then as Chairman of the
Council of Economic Advisers during 1995-1997, in which capacity he also served as a member of the cabinet. He became deeply involved in environmental issues, which included serving on the
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, and helping draft a new law for toxic wastes (which was never passed).
Stiglitz's most important contribution in this period was helping define a new economic philosophy, a "third way", which postulated the important, but limited, role of government, that unfettered markets often did not work well, but that government was not always able to correct the limitations of markets. The academic research that he had been conducting over the preceding 25 years provided the intellectual foundations for this "third way".
When President Bill Clinton was re-elected, he asked Stiglitz to continue to serve as Chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers for another term. But he had already been approached by the World Bank, to be its senior vice president for development policy and its chief economist.
As the World Bank began its ten-year review of the transition of the former Communist countries to the market economy it unveiled failures of the countries that had followed the International Monetary Fund (IMF) shock therapy policies - both in terms of the declines in GDP and increases in poverty - that were even worse than the worst that most of its critics had envisioned at the onset of the transition. Clear links existed between the dismal performances and the policies that the IMF had advocated, such as the voucher privatization schemes and excessive monetary stringency. Meanwhile, the success of a few countries that had followed quite different strategies suggested that there were alternatives that could have been followed. The U.S. Treasury had put enormous pressure on the World Bank to silence his criticisms of the policies which they and the IMF had pursued.
Stiglitz always had a poor relationship with Treasury Secretary Lawrence Summers. In 2000, Summers successfully petitioned for Stiglitz's removal, supposedly in exchange for World Bank President James Wolfensohn's re-appointment – an exchange that Wolfensohn denies took place. Whether Summers ever made such a blunt demand is questionable – Wolfensohn claims he would "have told him to fuck himself".
Stiglitz resigned from the World Bank in January 2000, a month before his term expired. The Bank's president, James Wolfensohn, announced Stiglitz's resignation in November 1999 and also announced that Stiglitz would stay on as ''"special advisor to the president"'', and would chair the search committee for a successor.
:"Joseph E. Stiglitz said today [Nov. 24, 1999] that he would resign as the World Bank's chief economist after using the position for nearly three years to raise pointed questions about the effectiveness of conventional approaches to helping poor countries."
In this role, he continued criticism of the IMF, and, by implication, the US Treasury Department. In April 2000, in an article for ''The New Republic'', he wrote:
:"''They’ll say the IMF is arrogant. They’ll say the IMF doesn’t really listen to the developing countries it is supposed to help. They’ll say the IMF is secretive and insulated from democratic accountability. They’ll say the IMF’s economic ‘remedies’ often make things worse – turning slowdowns into recessions and recessions into depressions. And they’ll have a point. I was chief economist at the World Bank from 1996 until last November, during the gravest global economic crisis in a half-century. I saw how the IMF, in tandem with the U.S. Treasury Department, responded. And I was appalled''."
The article was published a week before the annual meetings of the World Bank and IMF and provoked a strong response. It proved too strong for Summers and, yet more lethally, Stiglitz's protector-of-sorts at the World Bank, Wolfensohn. Wolfensohn had privately empathised with Stiglitz's views, but this time was worried for his second term, which Summers had threatened to veto. Stanley Fisher, deputy managing director of the IMF, called a special staff meeting and informed at that gathering that Wolfensohn had agreed to fire Stiglitz. Meanwhile, the Bank's External Affairs department told the press that Stiglitz had not been fired, his post had merely been abolished.
In a September 19, 2008 radio interview with Aimee Allison and Philip Maldari on Pacifica Radio's KPFA 94.1 FM in Berkeley, California, Stiglitz implied that President Clinton and his economic advisors would not have backed the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) had they been aware of stealth provisions, inserted by lobbyists, that they overlooked.
Initiative for Policy Dialogue
In July 2000 Stiglitz founded the
Initiative for Policy Dialogue (IPD), with support of the Ford, Rockefeller, McArthur, and Mott Foundations and the Canadian and Swedish governments, to enhance democratic processes for decision-making in developing countries and to ensure that a broader range of alternatives are on the table and more stakeholders are at the table.
Commission of Experts on Reforms of the International Monetary and Financial System
In 2009, Stiglitz chaired the
Commission of Experts on Reforms of the International Monetary and Financial System, informally known as the Stiglitz Commission, which was convened by the
President of the United Nations General Assembly "to review the workings of the
global financial system, including major bodies such as the
World Bank and the
IMF, and to suggest steps to be taken by Member States to secure a more
sustainable and
just global economic order".
Support to the 2011 Spanish Protests
On July 25, 2011, Stiglitz participated to the "I Foro Social del 15M" organized in
Madrid (
Spain) expressing his support to the
2011 Spanish protests. During an informal speech, he made a brief review of some of the problems in Europe and in the United States, the serious unemployment rate and the situation in Greece. "This is an opportunity for economic contribution social measures," argued Stiglitz, who made a critical speech about the way authorities are handling the political exit to the crisis. He encouraged those present to respond to the "bad ideas", not with indifference, but with "good ideas". "This does not work, you have to change it," he said.
Books
Along with his technical economic publications (he has published over 300 technical articles), Stiglitz is the author of books on issues from patent law to abuses in international trade.
''Freefall: America, Free Markets, and the Sinking of the World Economy'' (2010)
In ''Freefall: America, Free Markets, and the Sinking of the World Economy'', Stiglitz discusses the causes of the 2008 recession/depression and goes on to propose reforms needed to avoid a repetition of a similar crisis, advocating government intervention and regulation in a number of areas. Among the policy-makers he criticises are George W. Bush, Larry Summers, and Barack Obama.
This book does not require an economics background in order to be of value to the reader. Rather it explains Stiglitz's views on the recent economic crisis in terms which make it relevant to the average homeowner, retirement investor, and voter in the United States. He explains how without fundamental changes in economic policy and regulation the position of the US in the world political and economic arena may deteriorate significantly.
''The Three Trillion Dollar War: The True Cost of the Iraq Conflict'' (2008)
''
The Three Trillion Dollar War'' examines the full cost of the Iraq War, including many hidden costs. The book also discusses the extent to which these costs will be imposed for many years to come, paying special attention to the enormous expenditures that will be required to care for very large numbers of wounded veterans. Stiglitz was openly critical of George W. Bush at the time the book was released.
''Stability with Growth: Macroeconomics, Liberalization and Development'' (2006)
In ''
Stability with Growth: Macroeconomics, Liberalization and Development'', Stiglitz, José Antonio Ocampo (United Nations Under-Secretary-General for Economic and Social Affairs, until 2007), Shari Spiegel (Managing Director, Initiative for Policy Dialogue - IPD), Ricardo Ffrench-Davis (Main Adviser, Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean -
ECLAC) and Deepak Nayyar (Vice Chancellor, University of Delhi) discuss the current debates on macroeconomics, capital market liberalization and development, and develop a new framework within which one can assess alternative policies. They explain their belief that the
Washington Consensus has advocated narrow goals for development (with a focus on price stability) and prescribed too few policy instruments (emphasizing monetary and fiscal policies), and places unwarranted faith in the role of markets. The new framework focuses on real stability and long-term sustainable and equitable growth, offers a variety of non-standard ways to stabilize the economy and promote growth, and accepts that market imperfections necessitate government interventions. Policy-makers have pursued stabilization goals with little concern for growth consequences, while trying to increase growth through structural reforms focused on improving economic efficiency. Moreover, structural policies, such as capital market liberalization, have had major consequences for economic stability. This book challenges these policies by arguing that stabilization policy has important consequences for long-term growth and has often been implemented with adverse consequences. The first part of the book introduces the key questions and looks at the objectives of economic policy from different perspectives. The third part presents a similar analysis for capital market liberalization.
''Making Globalization Work'' (2006)
''
Making Globalization Work'' surveys the inequities of the global economy, and the mechanisms by which developed countries exert an excessive influence over developing nations. Dr. Stiglitz argues that through tariffs, subsidies, an over-complex patent system and pollution, the world is being both economically and politically destabilised. Stiglitz argues that strong, transparent institutions are needed to address these problems. He shows how an examination of incomplete markets can make corrective government policies desirable.
Stiglitz is an exception to the general pro-globalization view of professional economists, according to economist Martin Wolf. Stiglitz argues that economic opportunities are not widely enough available, that financial crises are too costly and too frequent, and that the rich countries have done too little to address these problems. ''Making Globalization Work'' had sold more than two million copies.
''Fair Trade for All'' (2005)
''New Paradigm for Monetary Economics'' (2004)
''The Roaring Nineties: A New History of the World's Most Prosperous Decade'' (2003)
''The Roaring Nineties"'' is Stiglitz' analysis of the boom and bust of the 1990s. Presented from an insider's point of view, firstly as chair of President Clinton's Council of Economic Advisors, and later as chief economist of the World Bank, it continues his argument on how misplaced faith in free-market ideology led to the global economic issues of today, with a perceptive focus on US policies.
''Globalization and Its Discontents'' (2002)
In ''
Globalization and Its Discontents'', Stiglitz argues that what are often called "developing economies" are, in fact, not developing at all, and puts much of the blame on the IMF.
Stiglitz bases his argument on the themes that his decades of theoretical work have emphasized: namely, what happens when people lack the key information that bears on the decisions they have to make, or when markets for important kinds of transactions are inadequate or don't exist, or when other institutions that standard economic thinking takes for granted are absent or flawed. Stiglitz stresses the point: "Recent advances in economic theory" (in part referring to his own work) "have shown that whenever information is imperfect and markets incomplete, which is to say always, and especially in developing countries, then the invisible hand works most imperfectly." As a result, Stiglitz continues, governments can improve the outcome by well-chosen interventions. Stiglitz argues that when families and firms seek to buy too little compared to what the economy can produce, governments can fight recessions and depressions by using expansionary monetary and fiscal policies to spur the demand for goods and services. At the microeconomic level, governments can regulate banks and other financial institutions to keep them sound. They can also use tax policy to steer investment into more productive industries and trade policies to allow new industries to mature to the point at which they can survive foreign competition. And governments can use a variety of devices, ranging from job creation to manpower training to welfare assistance, to put unemployed labor back to work and cushion human hardship.
Stiglitz complains bitterly that the IMF has done great damage through the economic policies it has prescribed that countries must follow in order to qualify for IMF loans, or for loans from banks and other private-sector lenders that look to the IMF to indicate whether a borrower is creditworthy. The organization and its officials, he argues, have ignored the implications of incomplete information, inadequate markets, and unworkable institutions—all of which are especially characteristic of newly developing countries. As a result, Stiglitz argues, the IMF has often called for policies that conform to textbook economics but do not make sense for the countries to which the IMF is recommending them. Stiglitz seeks to show that these policies have been disastrous for the countries that have followed them.
''Whither Socialism?''
''
Whither Socialism?'' is based on Stiglitz's Wicksell Lectures, presented at the
Stockholm School of Economics in 1990 and presents a summary of
information economics and the theory of markets with imperfect information and imperfect competition, as well as being a critique of both free market and market socialist approaches (see Roemer critique, op. cit.). Stiglitz explains how the
neoclassical, or
Walrasian model (''"Walrasian economics"'' refers to the result of the process which has given birth to a formal representation of
Adam Smith's notion of the "invisible hand", along the lines put forward by
Leon Walras and encapsulated in the general equilibrium model of
Arrow-Debreu), may have wrongly encouraged the belief that
market socialism could work. Stiglitz proposes an alternative model, based on the
information economics established by the Greenwald-Stiglitz theorems.
One of the reasons Stiglitz sees for the critical failing in the standard neoclassical model, on which market socialism was built, is its failure to consider the problems that arise from lack of perfect information and from the costs of acquiring information. He also identifies problems arising from its assumptions concerning completeness.
Papers and conferences
Stiglitz wrote a series of papers and held a series of conferences explaining how such information uncertainties may have influence on everything from unemployment to lending shortages. As the chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers during the Clinton Administration and former chief economist at the
World Bank, Stiglitz was able to put some of his views into action. For example, he was an outspoken critic of quickly opening up financial markets in developing countries. These markets rely on access to good financial data and sound bankruptcy laws, but he argued that many of these countries didn't have the regulatory institutions needed to ensure that the markets would operate soundly.
He co-authored a paper titled "Implications of the New Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac Risk-Based Capital Standard" with Peter Orszag in 2002 in which they concluded "on the basis of historical experience, the risk to the government from a potential default on GSE debt is effectively zero."
Private life
Stiglitz married for the third time on October 28, 2004, to
Anya Schiffrin, who works at the
School of International and Public Affairs at
Columbia University.
Publications
; Books:
2010, ''Freefall: America, Free Markets, and the Sinking of the World Economy'' ISBN 978-0393075960, W. W. Norton.
2010, ''Time for a Visible Hand: Lessons from the 2008 World Financial Crisis'' ISBN 978-0-19-957880-1, edited with Stephany Griffith-Jones and José Antonio Ocampo, Oxford University Press, 2010
2008, ''The Three Trillion Dollar War'' ISBN 978-0-39-306701-9; by Joseph Stiglitz and Linda Bilmes, W. W. Norton.
2006, ''Making Globalization Work'' ISBN 0-393-06122-1, Penguin Books, August 2006.
2006, ''Stability with Growth: Macroeconomics, Liberalization, and Development'' ISBN 0-19-928814-3 (Initiative for Policy Dialogue Series C); by Joseph E. Stiglitz, Jose Antonio Ocampo, Shari Spiegel, Ricardo Ffrench-Davis, and Deepak Nayyar; Oxford University Press 2006
1996, ''Whither Socialism ?'' Stiglitz, Joseph E., (Wicksell Lectures), MIT Press, January 1996.
2000, ''Frontiers of Development Economics: The Future in Perspective'', edited with Gerald M. Meier, World Bank, May 2000.
2001, ''Rethinking the East Asian Miracle'', edited with Shahid Yusuf, World Bank and Oxford University Press.
2002, ''Principles of Macroeconomics'', third edition, with Carl E. Walsh, W.W. Norton & Company, March 2002.
2002, ''Economics'', Third Edition, with Carl E. Walsh, W.W. Norton & Company, April 2002.
2002, ''Peasants Versus City-Dwellers: Taxation and the Burden of Economic Development'', with Raaj K. Sah, Oxford University Press, April 2002.
2002, ''Globalization and Its Discontents'', W.W. Norton & Company, June 2002.
2003,''Towards a New Paradigm in Monetary Economics'', with Bruce Greenwald, Cambridge University Press. Cambridge. Description and chapter-preview links.
2003, ''The Roaring Nineties'', W.W. Norton & Company, forthcoming in October 2003.
''Fair Trade for All: How Trade Can Promote Development'' (Initiative for Policy Dialogue Series C)– by Joseph E. Stiglitz, Andrew Charlton; Hardcover
2000, 3rd ed. ''Economics of the Public Sector.''
2002, ''The Rebel Within: Joseph Stiglitz and the World Bank'' by Joseph E. Stiglitz (Editor), Ha-Joon Chang (Editor), ISBN 1-898855-91-9, Anthem Press, Wimbledon Publishing Company (Paperback - February 25, 2002)
2005, ''The Development Round Of Trade Negotiations In The Aftermath Of Cancun'' by Joseph E. Stiglitz, Andrew Charlton (Paperback - January 30, 2005)
2005, ''A Chance For The World Bank'' by Joseph P Stiglitz (Foreword), Jozef Ritzen, ISBN 1-84331-162-3, Anthem Press, Wimbledon Publishing Company (Paperback - May 30, 2005)
1986, 'Economics of the Public Sector' by J.E.Stiglitz ISBN 0-393-96651-8, W.W.Norton, New York. (Re-printed 1988, 2000)
1981, 'Theory of Commodity Price Stabilization' by David M.G. Newbery and Joseph E. Stiglitz ISBN 0198284179 ISBN 978-0198284178, Oxford University Press [Hardcover: 512 pages]
''Readings in the Modern Theory of Economic Growth'' by Joseph E. Stiglitz (Editor), Hirofumi Uzawa (Editor)
; Book chapters:
2009. "Regulation and Failure," in David Moss and John Cisternino (eds.), ''New Perspectives on Regulation'', ch. 1, pp. 11-23. Cambridge: The Tobin Project.
2001, New Ideas About Old Age Security: Toward Sustainable Pension Systems in the 21st Century , edited with Robert Holzmann, World Bank, January 2001.
; Selected scholarly articles
2007, "Prizes, Not Patents" post-autistic economics review, issue no. 42
1998, Distinguished lecture on economics in government: The private uses of public interests: Incentives and institutions. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 12, 3–22.
1998, ''Redefining the Role of the State - What should it do ? How should it do it ? And how should these decisions be made?'' Paper presented at the Tenth Anniversary of MITI Research Institute, Tokyo, March 1998.
1996, The World Bank Research Observer: No 2: August 1996 by Joseph Stiglitz
1993, “Post Walrasian and post Marxian economics,” ''Journal of Economic Perspectives'', vol. 7, pp. 109–14
1993, “Market socialism and neoclassical economics,” in Bardhan, P. K. and Roemer, J. E. (eds.), ''Market Socialism. The Current Debate'', New York: Oxford University Press
1989, “Principal and agent,” in J. Eatwell, M. Milgate and P. Newman (eds.), ''The New Palgrave. Allocation, Information and Markets''. New York: W. W. Norton
1987, “The causes and consequences of the dependence of quality on prices”, ''Journal of Economic Literature'', vol. 25, pp. 1–48
1981 (with A. Weiss), "Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfect Information", ''American Economic Review'', vol. 71, pp. 393–410
1977 (with A.K. Dixit), “Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diversity”, ''American Economic Review'', vol. 67, pp. 297–308
1976 (with M. Rothschild), “Equilibrium in Competitive Insurance Markets: An Essay on the Economics of Imperfect Information”, ''Quarterly Journal of Economics'', vol. 90, pp. 629–650.
1974, “Incentives and Risk Sharing in Sharecropping”, ''Review of Economic Studies'', Vol. 41, No. 2, 219-255.
1974, “Alternative Theories of Wage Determination and Unemployment in LDCs: The Labour Turnover Model”, ''Quarterly Journal of Economics'', vol. 81, pp. 194–227
1971 (with M. Rothschild), “Increasing Risk: II. Its Economic Consequences”, ''Journal of Economic Theory'', Vol. 3, pp. 66–84
1970 (with M. Rothschild), “Increasing Risk: I. A Definition”, ''Journal of Economic Theory'', Vol. 2, pp. 225–243
; Articles in popular press:
2011, "Of the 1%, by the 1%, for the 1%", Vanity Fair, May 2011
2010, Review of
2009, "Wall Street’s Toxic Message", Vanity Fair, July 2009
2009, "America's socialism for the rich", The Guardian, June 2009
2009, "Capitalist Fools", Vanity Fair, January 2009
2007, "The Economic Consequences of Mr. Bush", Vanity Fair, December 2007 Issue
2007, Where is the World Going To, Mr. Stiglitz? directed by Jacques Sarasin, First Run Features.
2002, "Implications of the New Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac Risk-based Capital Standard", for FannieMae Volume I, Issue 2 March 2002
; Video and online sources:
2010, Freefall: Joseph Stiglitz at the Commonwealth Club
2008, The Three Trillion Dollar War a panel discussion with Joseph Stiglitz and Linda Bilmes regarding their new book, `''The Three Trillion Dollar War: The True Cost of the Iraq Conflict''.` Feb 28, 2008 at Columbia University.
2007, Where is the World Going To, Mr. Stiglitz? directed by Jacques Sarasin, First Run Features.
World Bank Video presentation
Online access to Stiglitz published papers, at his own website
See also
List of economists
List of Jewish Nobel laureates
References
External links
Joseph E. Stiglitz at Columbia University
* Joseph Stiglitz committee chair profile at Committee on Global Thought at Columbia University
Information and the Change in the Paradigm in Economics 2001 lecture at NobelPrize.org
Profile and Papers at Research Papers in Economics/RePEc
Publications at the National Bureau of Economic Research
Column archives at Project Syndicate
Joseph Stiglitz with Matthew Bishop at the 92nd Street Y, January 2010
Interview at The Commonwealth Club, February 2010
Free Markets and the World Economy with the Australian Broadcasting Corporation, July 2010
Category:Academics of the University of Oxford
Category:American anti-globalization writers
Category:American economists
Category:American Nobel laureates
Category:Amherst College alumni
Category:Ashkenazi Jews
Category:Clinton Administration personnel
Category:Columbia University faculty
Category:Development economists
Category:Development specialists
Category:New Keynesian economists
Category:Fellows of All Souls College, Oxford
Category:Fellows of Fitzwilliam College, Cambridge
Category:Fellows of Gonville and Caius College, Cambridge
Category:Fellows of the British Academy
Category:Fellows of the Econometric Society
Category:Information economists
Category:International development
Category:International Panel on Climate Change lead authors
Category:Jewish American writers
Category:Massachusetts Institute of Technology alumni
Category:Members of the United States National Academy of Sciences
Category:Members of the Pontifical Academy of Social Sciences
Category:Nobel laureates in Economics
Category:People from Gary, Indiana
Category:Princeton University faculty
Category:People associated with the University of Manchester
Category:Public economists
Category:Stanford University faculty
Category:United States Council of Economic Advisors
Category:World Bank Chief Economists
Category:Yale University faculty
Category:Keio University faculty
Category:1943 births
Category:Living people
Category:Foreign Members of the Royal Society
Category:Faculty of Sciences Po
Category:Gerald Loeb Award winners
ar:جوزيف ستيجلز
bn:জোসেফ স্টিগ্লিট্স
bg:Джоузеф Стиглиц
ca:Joseph Eugene Stiglitz
cs:Joseph Stiglitz
cy:Joseph Stiglitz
de:Joseph E. Stiglitz
et:Joseph Stiglitz
es:Joseph Stiglitz
eo:Joseph E. Stiglitz
fr:Joseph Eugene Stiglitz
gd:Joseph Stiglitz
ko:조지프 스티글리츠
io:Joseph E. Stiglitz
id:Joseph E. Stiglitz
it:Joseph Stiglitz
he:ג'וזף שטיגליץ
rw:Joseph Stiglitz
la:Iosephus E. Stiglitz
lt:Joseph Stiglitz
mk:Џозеф Стиглиц
mr:जोसेफ स्तिगलित्झ
nl:Joseph Eugene Stiglitz
ja:ジョセフ・E・スティグリッツ
no:Joseph E. Stiglitz
pnb:جازف سٹگلٹز
pl:Joseph E. Stiglitz
pt:Joseph Stiglitz
ro:Joseph Stiglitz
ru:Стиглиц, Джозеф Юджин
sl:Joseph Stiglitz
fi:Joseph Stiglitz
sv:Joseph Stiglitz
th:โจเซฟ สติกลิตส์
tr:Joseph E. Stiglitz
uk:Джозеф Стігліц
vi:Joseph Stiglitz
yo:Joseph E. Stiglitz
zh:约瑟夫·斯蒂格利茨